Madrid, 27 de Octubre de 2010 Seminario en el Instituto de Estudios Fiscales JOSÉ MARÍA ARRANZ Y CARLOS GARCÍA SERRANO (UNIVERSIDAD DE ALCALÁ) The interplay of the unemployment compensation system, fixed-term contracts and rehirings 5. 4. 3. 2. 1. Background Dataset Econometric specification Results Conclusions The interplay of the unemployment compensation system, fixed-term contracts and rehirings | z z Spanish case Æ two strands of research: • HSIPRE: Cons (only recipients, no control group); Pros (information on potential duration, level of benefits, types of benefit). Cebrián et al. (1995,1996); Jenkins and GarcíaSerrano (2004); Arranz and Muro (2004,2007); Alba et al. (2007). • EPA: Cons (information on receipt only, no level, no potential duration, no types of benefit); Pros (control group). Alba (1999); Bover et al. (2002); Toharia (1998); Cantó and Toharia (2003); Arranz et al. (2010). One conclusion: recipients remain longer in unemployment than non recipients, but the effect is in the short run, vanishing in the medium run. Previous study: “El sistema de protección por desempleo y la salida del paro” (PEE, 2010) Background 0 0 .1 0 .2 0 .3 0 .4 0 .5 0 .6 0 .7 0 .8 0 .9 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 7 8 9 P e r c e p t o r ( <1 a ñ o ) 6 10 12 13 14 P e r c e p t o r ( 1-3 a ñ o s) 11 15 16 18 19 20 P e r c e p t o r ( >3 a ñ o s) 17 21 23 24 No p e r c e p t o r 22 25 26 27 28 Función de permanencia de los perceptores de prestaciones y de los no perceptores, según duración del empleo anterior. Episodios de empleo finalizados en 2004 y 2005. MCVL (2004-2007) 29 298 59 63 Perceptores Prestación contributiva Prestación asistencial Subsidio >52 años o fijos discontinuos 31 28 123 33 91 198 (192) 175 (143) 136 (106) 130 145 (116) 75 (69) 165 (143) 75 (67) 60 88 (78) Duración no empleo Media Mediana 183 86 209 142 181 62 31 94 45 75 Duración empleo posterior Media Mediana Nota: Para los perceptores de prestaciones se puede distinguir la duración efectiva del período total de no empleo y la duración del período cubierto por las prestaciones. Entre paréntesis está la duración media y mediana del paro protegido de los perceptores de prestaciones. 134 242 Todos No perceptores Perceptores Duración empleo anterior Media Mediana Duración media y mediana (en días) de los episodios de empleo anterior, no empleo y empleo posterior de los individuos que transitan entre dos episodios de empleo, distinguiendo entre perceptores y no perceptores de prestaciones. Episodios de empleo que finalizan en 2004 y 2005. | | | | In USA : Katz and Meyer (1990), Fallick and Ryu (2007). In Europe: Winter-Ebmer(1998); Roed and Nordberg (2003); Jensen and Svarer, (2003); Mavroramas and Orme (2004); Alba, Arranz and Muñoz-Bullón (2007). Second, employer recall policies and/or implicit contracts between employers and workers are a key determinant of both the probability that individuals enter unemployment (via layoffs decisions) and that they leave unemployment (via search and rehire decisions). Third, the use of temporary layoffs on the part of firms and the existence of positive recall prospects on the part of (a portion of) workers may affect the impact of labour market interventions (recruitment incentives and subsidies for the training of the unemployed). Therefore, recall expectations can alter the conclusions reached by the evaluations of such programmes. z z An analysis of rehirings is necessary for a proper understanding of the determinants of unemployment durations and unemployment policies. First, studies show that rehirings are common (1/3 unemployed workers) Background o the interplay between UCS, the use of fixed term contracts and the layoffrehire process. o Discussing “experience rating”. o Examining - From job to job. - From non-employment to a job. - From insured unemployment into a job, nonemployment or other benefits. the importance of rehirings in labour market transitions in Spain: o Documenting Contributions of the paper: Background In Spain, the lack of experience rating in the UCS and seasonal demand fluctuations may provide strong incentives for implicit contracts. At the same time, the flexible availability of fixed­ term contracts may be a reflection of these incentives since, when fixed term contracts end, no costs arise for employers. In this context, unemployment benefit entitlements may create incentives for employers to offer fixed­ term instead of permanent contracts, since the end of contract gives the firm employment flexibility and leaves open the future rehiring. | | | Background | | | | | z z z Employment spells ending in 2004 or 2005. 16-59 years old. Exclusions: self employment and agricultural sector. Social Security records with information of employment and covered unemployment spells of a 4% random sample of Spanish individuals who have a relationship with the Social Security in years 2004-2007. Individual characteristics (gender, age, nationality, province). Firm and job attributes (employer size, industry affiliation, qualification level, type of contract, dates of start and end of employment spells and reason for termination of employment spell). Unemployment benefit spells (types of benefits -UI, UA, others-, number of days of benefit receipt). Sample selection: Dataset: MCVL 2004-2007 Lost job Insured unemployment (UI,UA) Non-employment Employment Recall job New job Other benefits Non-employment Recall job New job Recall job New job Transitions of job losers to employment, non-employment and insured unemployment (in periods t+1 and t+2). Transitions of job losers to employment, non-employment and insured unemployment (in period t+1), by types of contract. Employment periods ending in 2004 or 2005. Spain: MCVL. Transitions of job losers to employment, non-employment and insured unemployment (in period t+1) and from these states to a new job, a recall job, non-employment or other benefits (in period t+2), by types of contract. Employment periods ending in 2004 or 2005. Spain: MCVL. Distribution of spells of non-employment and insured unemployment and weeks of non-employment and unemployment, by types of contract and spell outcome. Employment periods ending in 2004 or 2005. Spain: MCVL. % 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 UA_ reh iring s UI_ reh iring s NE_ reh iring s Months 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Recalls as a fraction of all spells of non­ employment and unemployment by duration and types of transition. % 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Mont h s z 10 11 12 R ecipien ts_F ixe d-ter m 13 R ec ipien ts _Pe rma nen t pe r ta sk R ecipien ts_o pen e nde d NE_F ixe d-t er m NE_Pe rma nen t pe r ta sk NE_o pen e nde d 14 1 5 16 Recalls as a fraction of all spells of nonemployment and unemployment by duration, types of transition and types of contract in previous job. 17 H azard 0 0.001 0.002 0.003 0.004 0.005 0.006 0.007 0.008 0.009 1 2 3 4 5 6 8 9 10 11 12 Rehirings(Non-employment) 7 13 15 16 17 18 19 Months Rehirings(Benefits) 14 21 22 23 24 25 26 NEW JOB(Non-employment) 20 27 29 30 31 32 NEW JOB(Benefits) 28 33 34 35 36 Recall and new job hazards from uninsured non­ employment and insured unemployment. Hazard 0 0.001 0.002 0.003 0.004 0.005 0.006 0.007 0.008 0.009 0.01 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13 Rehirings(UI) 11 14 16 17 18 19 Months Rehirings(UA) 15 21 22 23 NEW JOB(UI) 20 24 26 27 28 NEW JOB(UA) 25 29 30 31 32 33 34 Recall and new job hazards from UI and UA. 35 36 | | | Where dij=1 if duration is complete n ª 3 ª h (t) ºdij ª t º º ij L = ∏«∏« » «∏(1−hik )»» (1−hij (t))»¼ ¬ k=1 i=1 « j=1 « ¼»¼ ¬ ¬ Discrete time competing risk model Spell can end in j states: z j=1 re-employment through a new job (ref.). z j=2 re-employment through a recall job. z j=3 remaining unemployment. Assuming independence in the competing risks: Econometric specification k =1 L=∏ t 2 ' ' 1 + ¦ exp(Dk α m + X k β m + v m ) m =1 ª 2 º ' ' exp « ¦ (D α + X β + v ) c » k m k m m mk m = 1 ¼ ¬ The contribution to the likelihood function for a single individual is : where: x: vector of explanatory variables ȕ: parameter vector Į: baseline hazard v: u nobserved heterogeneity m: indicators for the transitions to each possible destination state at time k. | Econometric specification z • Industry: recall hazard rates are larger in sectors such as “Health”, “Education” and “Transport”. • Firm size: workers previously employed in large firms exhibit higher recall hazards. • Level of qualification: white-collar workers holding jobs that require higher qualification levels are more likely to be recalled faster by their previous employer. • Types of contract: workers who held a permanent per-task contract exhibit a noticeably higher recall hazard as compared to workers with a fixed-term contract and, above all, with workers with an open-ended contract. • Tenure in previous job: the chance of being recalled diminishes with the duration of the previous job (insured unemployment). Job and firm characteristics are relevant: Results Results of the competing risks duration data model: recall hazard rates. | | z z • Permanent per-task contracts (74%) and other fixed-term contracts (43-44%). • Large firms. • Collective services. The fact that Spanish UCS is not experience rated and the extended use of fixed-term contracts facilitates short spells of employment and unemployment and make rehirings more likely (30% of job losers moving through the UCS return to their previous employers). The degree of cross subsidization is large in the Spanish labour market and concentrates in firms and industries with higher labour turnover and temporary employment and with more seasonal product fluctuations. Although recalls are widespread along the Spanish labour market, there are certain types of contracts, firms and sectors which concentrate many of them: New evidence on the importance of rehirings in labour market transitions. Special attention to the interplay between UCS, the use of fixed-term contracts and the layoff-rehire process. Conclusions z z These results suggest that there is room for the reform of the way the UCS is financed, in combination with changes in other labour market institutions. One proposal (Blanchard and Tirole, 2003) would be to transform the uniform payroll taxes to finance unemployment benefits into a layoff (or separation) tax so that firms using the UCS more intensely are the ones paying higher contribution rates. This would make employers to internalize the social costs associated with layoffs, reduce excessive job separations and eliminate (or at least reduce) cross-subsidization across firms and industries. Conclusions