LATIN AMERICAN ECONOMIC HISTORY

Anuncio
LATIN AMERICAN ECONOMIC HISTORY: LOOKING BACKWARDS FOR
THE FUTURE
Luis Bértola & Javier Rodríguez Weber
Documento On Line Nº 37
Abril 2015
ISSN: 1688-9037
ISSN: 1688-9037
Título-clave: Documentos de trabajo (Programa de Historia Económica y Social, Unidad Multidisciplinaria, Facultad de Ciencias Sociales,
Universidad de la República)
Título-clave abreviado: Documentos trab. (Programa Historia Económica Social, Unidad Multidisciplinaria, Facultad Cienc. Sociales, Univ. Repúb)
© Programa de Historia Económica y Social – Unidad Multidisciplinaria – Facultad de Ciencias
Sociales – Universidad de la República
Constituyente 1502, 4º piso.
Teléfono: (+598) 24136400
Fax: (+598) 24102769
Luis Bértola & Javier Rodríguez Weber
LATIN
AMERICAN
ECONOMIC
BACKWARDS FOR THE FUTURE
Documento On Line Nº 37
Abril 2015
ISSN: 1688-9037
HISTORY:
LOOKING
Latin American Economic History: looking backwards for the
future
Luis Bértola* and Javier Rodríguez Weber†
Abstract
The paper will explore different trends in Latin American economic history written in
different periods, relating them to contemporary academics, economic and political
debates in Latin America and in the developed world. It will highlight the extent to
which economic history in Latin America and Latin American historiography has
shown similar development patterns to the Western canon, where particular and
distinctive features can be found.
Key words: Latin America, economic history, development studies, political economy,
economics, historiography
JEL: A12 - B25 – B50 – N01- O54
*
Programa
de
Historia
Económica
y
Social,
Universidad
de
la
República,
Uruguay.
y
Social,
Universidad
de
la
República,
Uruguay.
luis.bertola@cienciassociales.edu.uy
†
Programa
de
Historia
Económica
javier.rodriguez@cienciassociales.edu.uy
La historia económica de América Latina: mirando al pasado en
busca del futuro
Luis Bértola‡ and Javier Rodríguez Weber§
Resumen
El documento analiza las diferentes tendencias por las que ha transitado la historia
económica latinoamericana escrita en distintos períodos, ubicándolos en relación a los
debates contemporáneos en los ámbitos académicos y políticos, tanto en América Latina
como en el mundo desarrollado. Su objetivo es analizar las similitudes y deferencias de
la historia económica de América latina, así como de su historiografía, respecto a la
trayectoria del el mundo desarrollado.
Palabras clave: América Latina, historia económica, estudios del desarrollo, economía
política, economía, historiografía
JEL: A12 - B25 – B50 – N01- O54
‡
Programa
de
Historia
Económica
y
Social,
Universidad
de
la
República,
Uruguay.
y
Social,
Universidad
de
la
República,
Uruguay.
luis.bertola@cienciassociales.edu.uy
§
Programa
de
Historia
Económica
javier.rodriguez@cienciassociales.edu.uy
1- Introduction
Latin America has experienced a long term process of clear divergence from
developed countries. At the same time, it has been a dynamic region, in the sense that it has
been growing at world averages and has shown standards of living that are, on average,
clearly above those of the poorer regions of the world (Bértola and Ocampo 2012).
These are some probable explanations why Latin America has a relatively strong
tradition in economic history and to why Latin Americans have searched for an
explanation for its relative backwardness and for clues in order to find the path to
development in the economic history of the region. Compared to other regions, Latin
American economic historical bibliography has been more interested in the future than in
the past. Part of the reason is that the type of economic transformations that occurred in
developed regions are present challenges in Latin America. To some extent, there is a tacit
or explicit idea that developed countries are the mirror in which Latin America is looking
for its future.
The 1960s and 1970s were the golden age of Latin American economic history. By
that time, economists were mainly developmental economists. This means that they were
focused on long-term performance and that the main explanations were to be found in
particular structures of production and institutional arrangements, both at the domestic and
international level. By then, historians were mainly influenced by Annales-like and
Marxist thinking, in which institutions power and politics were always present, but mainly
articulated through the economic determinants of social life. Even sociologists and the
emerging political scientists were still very much concerned with the interaction between
economics, social structures and politics, and they did not find a problem in letting
economics play the determinant role. Within this historiography economic history became
a field of convergence of the different social sciences.
At the same time, Latin American economic historical bibliography was very much
influenced by different ideological points of view, especially concerning the question on
whether the Western path of development was the one to be followed by Latin American
countries, by necessity or desire, or if progress was demanding alternative development
patterns. The 1980s and 1990s witnessed important changes. Most Latin American
countries abandoned the developmentalist agenda and moved towards the structural
1
reforms dominated by what was later known as the Washington Consensus. The decadence
of the big theories of economic and social change and of the communist experiments, the
almost complete dominance of neoclassical economics, the decreasing interest that
economics had for historians, and the increasing autonomy of both sociology and political
science, left economic history as a very marginal field in the social sciences, in clear
contrast with the glorious 1960s and 1970s.
The last two decades are showing a renaissance of economic history, in different
directions. Some general trends are the clearly diminished role played by big theories and
ideologies, a more professional approach to the construction of information and historical
facts, and an increasing attempt to connect local with other national experiences. A
positive outcome is the proliferation of research networks across countries and the
increasing institutionalization of international forums.
This chapter will explore different trends in Latin American economic history
written in different periods, relating them to contemporary academics, economic and
political debates in Latin America and in the developed world. It will highlight the extent
to which economic history in Latin America and Latin American historiography has shown
similar development patterns to the Western canon, where particular and distinctive
features can be found. We conclude with reflections on the future research agenda.
2. Up to the “Golden Age” (1970s and 1980s)
In 1970, a group of economic historians met in Lima, Perú, in what was called the
first Symposium of Latin American Economic History. The meeting had three goals: to
make a critical review of the state of the art of economic history in the continent, to discuss
the main problems and methods of the discipline, and to agree on a common research
agenda for the future. In the introduction to the volume which compiled the papers from
the conference, Heraclio Bonilla (1972:10) wrote that the state of economic history in the
different countries was “embryonic”. Moreover, according to Tulio Halperin (1972), Latin
American economic history was so recent that one could doubt of its mere existence. In
fact, the different papers dated the origins of the discipline not earlier than in the 1950s. It
was in the mid-century when the first books on economic history began to be published,
and this was no coincidence. As we will see later, the crisis of the export-led growth
2
model, which occurred in the interwar period, had a catalyzing effect on the development
of economic history.
Two main history writing traditions -often complementary- contributed to our
knowledge of the economic past during what we can call the pre-history of economic
history: a traditional nationalist tradition and Marxism. Latin American historiography,
from its origins until well into the 20th century, has been interested in the study of the
political process of recent born republics, usually as an act of patriotism and with the
explicit goal of contributing to consolidate the nation State and the creation of a national
identity. The study of the economic past was not totally absent in these studies, but it was
clearly not more than a complement for the explanation of political processes. This is, for
instance, the case of the Argentine Bartolomé Mitre, who focused on the role of the
economic expansion of the Litoral in the revolutionary process of his country, and of the
Uruguayan Pablo Blanco Acevedo, who highlighted the role played by the rivalry between
the harbors of Montevideo and Buenos Aires, as an important component of the creation of
Uruguayan nationality. Nonetheless, the main objective was still to assess the political
process: the criteria to analyze periods, and to find decisive benchmarks, were political.
Therefore, Bonilla (1972) stressed the need to use different criteria to analyze the
economic history of Latin America other than the political benchmarks.
The Marxist tradition is probably greatly responsible for the above-mentioned
features of Latin American economic history writings, in the sense that understanding the
past was a key element to understand and change the current situation. Luis Nieto Arteta´s
1942 Economía y cultura en la Historia de Colombia, was one of the pioneering works in
Colombian economic history (Meisel 2007: 586). In Chile, similar attempts were made by
authors like Julio Cesar Jobet (Ensayo crítico del desarrollo económico social de Chile,
1951) or Luis Vitale. Broadly speaking, the Marxist tradition stressed the semi-feudal
features of the Latin American societies and economies, and tended to assume that
capitalist relations of production had to be reinforced in order to develop the productive
forces than could make possible deeper transformations of social relations towards
socialism in the future. Implicit in these analyses was the idea that economic development
followed a universal pattern.
As we said, interest in economic history rose after 1930, a time when the old
certainties were put into question. However, as a research field it was born two decades
3
after World War II. Latin American economic history was the result of three traditions or
sources: the economics developed at the Economic Commission for Latin America
(ECLA), the Annales School and Marxism. The first one was a school deeply rooted in the
continent and spread mainly among economists. The others had their origin in Europe and
were mostly influenced by historians. However, as mentioned above, these traditions
tended to have an increasing interaction between them and also with contributions from
other social sciences such as sociology and the emerging political science, but also from
intellectuals participating in different political movements.
The 1930s were crucial in Latin American economic history and seriously impacted
on intellectual production in Latin America. However, this was a very slow movement.
The 1930s in almost all of Latin America were characterized by an increasing role played
by the State, trying to counteract the huge balance of payments problems arising from the
collapse of export prices and volumes. The first reactions were highly pragmatic. No
alternative theory to the orthodox was presented yet (Bértola and Ocampo 2012).
Nevertheless, as time went by, different bodies of theories regarding Latin
American long-run development appeared. They tried to find good explanations of the
need for State engagement in policy making in order to overcome what was then called
underdevelopment. This process was not totally endogenous. During the post-World War
II period, development economics arose as an alternative to both orthodox and Keynesian
economic thinking. What happened in Latin America was closely related to the
development of development economics. The Latin American Structuralist tradition
developed what was later called as the historical-structural method of analysis (Sunkel and
Paz 1970). It was assumed that economics could not rely on the hypothetic-deductive
approach, but that it had to be combined with the study of the particular characteristics
experienced by societies in a certain period of time. There were limits to general rules and
it was key to take into consideration that Latin America is a peripheral region of a world
dominated by industrialized countries. However, this approach is very common in the
social sciences so it is not fair to claim that this is a distinctive feature of Latin American
Structuralism (Rodríguez 2005).
What is of particular interest for us is that this approach fueled a huge amount of
economic research which departed from the assumption that development was a long-run
4
process, in which pure economic factors were strongly interacting with cultural, social and
political ones. Thus, a large amount of work was dedicated to interpret long-term
development in Latin America and important books were written about the continent as a
whole. The more influential ones were Sunkel and Paz (1970), Cardoso and Faletto (1969),
Celso Furtado (1969). These general works were paralleled by a huge amount of national
studies, covering different periods and economic sectors.
A central component of this line of research was the creation of the Economic
Commission for Latin America in 1948, which was dynamically led by the Argentine Raúl
Prebisch during this period. The son of a German immigrant and a daughter of the
decadent local aristocracy in Tucumán, Prebisch summarized the contradiction of the time
between the promises of an industrial world and the reality of a poor periphery of settler
economies. Facing the crisis of the 1930s as a distinguished civil servant stimulated his
ideas about the need to introduce deep changes in the productive structure of a primarybased country, with drastic changes in demand and prices and limited capacity to absorb
the benefits of technical change. Prebisch transformed ECLA into a huge think tank which
attracted the best Latin American scholars (such as Furtado and Sunkel) and promoted a
research agenda that combined deep theoretical thinking, the creation of modern systems
of information and statistics, and a deep engagement in current problems and policy
making. The impact of the ECLA tradition on Latin American economic history writing is
difficult to overestimate since it has gone far beyond the Latin American experience. One
single example may suffice: the intensive debate on the tendency of the terms of trade of
primary products vis-à-vis manufactures is based on the so-called Prebisch-Singer thesis
and it is a debate that continues to this day.
The Structuralist tradition had a particular interest in the study of center-periphery
relations, i.e. the different forms of subordinate development, either under formal colonial
rules or under informal forms of dependency (economic, commercial, financial,
technological, and even cultural). Nonetheless, already in the late 1950s the focus shifted
more and more towards the study of domestic factors blocking development: inequality in
asset distribution (particularly land), concentration in the commercial sector, the cultural
behavior of the elites (rent-seeking and luxurious consumption patterns), the weaknesses of
the State, deficient educational system, among others.
5
In all of these fields, the Structuralist tradition promoted a great deal of studies.
Even if they could hardly be labeled as economic history writings, they were, without any
doubt, important contributions to the understanding of the economic history of the region.
However, in doing that, this tradition did not constitute a break with what we can call the
Western Canon of the time: Structuralism, even in focusing on the particular features of
Latin American development, continued to see Latin America in the mirror of Western
Development.
While economists looked at the history of Latin American economies in search for
answers to the difficulties of present economic development, historians were doing… the
same, but adopting the principles of the Annales-school and adapting Marxism to the
reality of the continent.
The French Historical Revolution1 was welcomed by many young historians who
were more interested in understanding the economic and social problems of the present
than in the exaltation of the national heroes of the past. Many were also looking for
answers which allowed them to contribute to change their reality. They were intelectuales
comprometidos (committed intellectuals). Besides the differences between Latin American
countries, historians were interested in the Annales School for three main reasons. As an
academic movement, the Annales historians fought against a historical tradition centred in
the politics of the Nation-State. Secondly, the long-run emphasis was considered
particularly suited for Latin America, as many of the central problems of the present –like
the unequal distribution of land and its political and social consequences, or the problem of
dependency foreign powers- had its origins in colonial times. Thirdly, they were seduced
by the goal of total history, which they considered essential to deal with the complexities
of the development process of Latin America. Peru provides a good example of this.
Manuel Burga (2005: 176-206) recounts the way in which, since 1960, different Peruvian
historians went to Paris to study at the Ecole Practique des Hautes Études. The first one
was Pablo Macera. Many others followed –like Heraclio Bonilla and Manuel Burga
himself. After his return, Pablo Macera spread the ideas and works of the Annales School
from his chair in Peruvian History and he gathered a group of young scholars who often
1
This is the title of the book written by Burke (1990).
6
met in his own house. Due to his studies in France, Macera gained interest in economic
history. On his return to Peru, he focused on the long-term study of the Andean Hacienda.
According to Burga, he was interested in prices, wages, and commerce, conceived as the
quantitative outcomes of social history. Ruggiero Romano and Pierre Vilar were his
favourite authors. Macera combined the lessons he learned from French historiography
with local authors, who, like José Carlos Mariátegui (1928), had focused on the point of
view of the indigenous population and culture. The synthesis was an interpretation of
Peruvian history as a permanent defeat of this indigenous population, a story of continuous
frustration and permanent degradation and exploitation. From his point of view, historical
writings were important for revealing the exploitation of the Andean population. The
Peruvian Revolution, he thought, should vindicate the indigenous people and its culture.
Between 1965 and 1975, a dozen young scholars travelled from Perú to Paris to
study with the masters of the Annales School, especially with Ruggiero Romano2. The
titles and themes of their books speak about their goal: to apply what they learned in Paris
to the Latin American development problems. Thus, in Guano and Burguesía en el Perú,
Heraclio Bonilla studied the internal and external mechanisms which prevented that the
exploitation of a rich mineral resource –the guano- became a path to development. In his
book De la encomienda a la hacienda capitalista. El valle de Jequetepeque ss. XVI-XX,
Manuel Burga attempted to analyse the geography and economy of one region through
centuries, from the very beginning of the conquest to the present. Both books, although
different, are examples of the way in which the Annales School contributed to the
renovation of Latin American historiography, and more specifically, economic history.
The influence of the Annales School went far beyond those who went to Paris.
Historians like Mario Góngora and Rolando Mellafe in Chile, Enrique Tandeter and Jorge
Gelman, from Argentina, or José Pedro Barrán and Benjamín Nahúm, from Uruguay, to
cite just a few, approached history in the characteristic way of the Annales historians.
Some of them studied in the Ecole, others not, but all of them applied the principles of the
2
Any analysis of the influence of Annales School in Latin American economic history would be
incomplete without a specific reference to Ruggiero Romano. An Italian born historian, Romano not only had
a seminar on Latin American history, but also oriented the dissertations of most of the Latin American
scholars who studied in the Ecole (Arcondo 2003).
7
Annales School in a creative way trying to understand the evolution of Latin American
institutions in the long-run, especially in the rural sector.
Marxism was the other historiographical tradition which highly influenced
historians interested in the economic past. The first attempts to apply historical materialism
to Latin American history were mostly interpretative and simplistic, in the vein of what
Eric Hobsbawm called “vulgar Marxism”. But things changed in the sixties and seventies,
when Marxist economic historians combined erudition and deep knowledge of the sources
with a non-dogmatic and creative use of Marxist theory. The analysis of the debate about
the prevailing mode of production in Latin American between the 16th and 19th centuries
will allow us to exemplify the characteristics of this approach to economic history.
The debate was triggered by the publication of Capitalism and Underdevelopment
in Latin America in 1967 written by the German-born economist and sociologist Andre
Gunder Frank, one of the fathers of the dependency theory and the concept of
‘development of underdevelopment’. In his opinion, Latin American underdevelopment
and western development were the two sides of the same coin, an idea shared by all
scholars who adopted the dependency approach. Much more controversial was his
assertion that the capitalist mode of production became preeminent in Latin American
economies from the very moment of the conquest. According to Gunder Frank, what
differentiates feudalism from capitalism was that the former was a closed economy, and
the latter was an open economy. As colonial Latin America produced commodities for
export since the 16th century, it was dominated by capitalism. A group of Latin American
scholars reviewed the book in what became known as the “Modes of Production Debate”
(Assadourian 1976). Authors like Juan Carlos Garavaglia, Carlos Sempat Assadourian,
Ernesto Laclau and Ciro Flamarion Santana Cardoso not only questioned the views of
Gunder Frank, but also attempted to build a better model of Latin American colonial
economies.
The debate was important because, although historical and theoretical in principle,
its interest went far beyond the academic world as it affected the politics of leftist parties at
a time of increasing social and political confrontation, as expressed by the Cuban
Revolution. If the colonial times could be assimilated to feudalism, then, Latin America
need to go through a capitalist period before more advanced socialist goals could be
achieved. On the contrary, if, as Gunder Frank argued, capitalism was the preeminent
8
economic system in the continent since 16th century, the revolution was feasible. As is
usual in Latin American economic history, the study of the past was a path to change the
present.
Many Latin American scholars taking part in the debate were critical of Frank’s
thesis, on theoretical and historical grounds. Theoretically, they questioned the definition
of feudalism and capitalism. They argued that to consider feudalism as a closed system
showed a great deal of ignorance about what was known about it. In the historical field,
they claimed that Frank presented an oversimplified view of Latin American colonial
history, which was refuted by historical evidence. Carlos Sempat Assadourian, -who
started his paper with a comment on the “hard reality of underdevelopment which affected
Latin America” in the 1960s- questioned the idea sustained by Frank, that the crisis of the
external sector -that linked the centres to the periphery- had positive impacts on the latter.
Assadourian had shown, in his earlier works, the key role played by the mining sector and
the big cities as centres of a much wider ‘economic space’ composed by the regions which
supplied many different inputs to the export sectors. Thus, the crisis of the external sector,
rather than diminishing exploitation, produced a depression of the whole economic and
social system.
Most Latin American historians agreed that talking about capitalism in the 16th
century made no sense, but they disagreed on how to characterize the colonial economic
system as feudal or something else. The most interesting view, in our opinion, was that of
Ciro Cardoso, who, following Witold Kula, argued in favour of a theory of ‘colonial
modes of production’. These, not present in Marx´s writings, included the ‘colonial fact’ i.e. the reality of economic and political dependency- as its first and most important
feature. Assuming that proposition as a starting point, the different colonial modes of
production -for example the colonial slave mode of production- should take into account
the differences in the labour regimes, demography and the characteristics of indigenous
civilizations and cultures throughout the continent.
In sum, in the critique of Frank’s thesis, Marxist Latin American historians
vindicated an economic history that was theoretically informed and empirically grounded.
This debate was, at the beginning, very much theoretical and political in character.
However, it fuelled a large amount of empirical research on the particular economic,
environmental, social, demographic and political contexts of the different Latin American
9
countries and regions. At a time when the process of industrialization had advanced in
Latin America and the National States were playing a more active role with the result of
strengthened universities and academic life, academic production increased significantly.
Moreover, the changing political climate in different countries forced scholars to move to
other countries, thus increasing the intellectual exchange and more profound consciousness
about Latin American diversity.
Tulio Halperin Dongui´s Contemporary History of Latin America, (Halperin 1969)
and Ciro Flamarión Santana Cardoso & Héctor Pérez Brignoli’s Historia Económica de
América Latina (Cardoso & Pérez Brignoli 1979) are two examples of the achievements
and high standard of economic historiography in Latin America.
Halperin´s book is a very good example of a history book which clearly relies on
the idea that economic forces play a decisive role in historical development, i.e. an
economic based total history. The book is subtle, very well-informed, full of regional and
national nuances and very well-written. It sheds light on the interplay between the
domestic determinants of historical events and the international sphere. Many editions of
the book were published and it was translated into many different languages. Seen from
today’s perspective, the book has all the shortcomings expected from this kind of literature:
lack of economic theory, lack of hard data, lack of crucial information on growth,
accumulation and other critical variables, etc. However, the book provided profound
insights on Latin American economic history, by combining the different schools of
thought prevailing at the time in a critical and creative manner.
The book by Cardoso & Pérez Brignoli is an example of a non-orthodox Marxist
approach to Latin American economic history. In short, C&PB’s argument is as follows.
Latin American colonial societies are based on three components: the European economy,
African pre‐colonial societies, and obviously the pre-Columbian civilizations. These
components combined in different ways in different parts of the region in response to local
environmental and social conditions. Societies developed as part or extension of the
European economy, but they also developed structures and dynamics of their own. The
different regions are identified by four different criteria: a) the colonial power (weak
explanatory power); b) the degree of connection to world markets (export centres,
subsidiary economies and marginal regions often overlap in the same space); c) the kind of
products, highly dependent on geography (mining centres, tropical products, the
10
production of foodstuffs and consumer goods for domestic markets), with big impacts on
techniques and social organization; and d) labour relations and the character of the
colonization process. Concerning the latter, the authors distinguish between different
regions. Firstly, the Euro‐Indian regions, which were the core areas of the pre-Columbian
civilizations and where colonization meant a redistribution of productive factors and the
imposition of forced labour on reorganized peasant communities in many different and
heterogeneous forms. Secondly, there were Euro‐African societies, i.e. more homogeneous
slave societies in regions suitable for tropical crops. Thirdly, there were Euro‐American
societies in temperate regions with low native population densities and increasing
European immigration. The various combinations of all these factors gave rise to a wide
variety of transitions to peripheral capitalism, with particular forms adopted by the liberal
reforms. The richness of this approach, the deep understanding of the interaction between
international and domestic forces, the interwoven effect of geographical, social and
cultural features, were unfortunately lost in the recent neo-institutional literature on Latin
America. The latter has tended to oversimplify the Latin American pattern of development
by searching for too general explanations.
3-Centrifugal forces and divorce: 1970s-1990s
Contrary to what happened during what we called the Golden Age of economic
history in Latin America, the following decades were characterized by centrifugal forces:
The separation of the Annales tradition, crisis within Marxism, weakening of development
economics, hegemony of neoclassical economics and repression of academic life in many
Latin American countries. As a result, economic history lost its central place among the
social sciences and started a process of transformation which resulted in a new generation
of more professional economic historians. However, they played a more marginal role in
the social sciences.
The political atmosphere changed between the 1970s and 1990s. The collapse of
real socialism, the crisis of Keynesianism and the hegemony of neo-classical and
monetarist approaches impacted worldwide. In Latin America, this process went hand in
hand with the crisis of State-led growth, and, in the countries with higher living standards
were structural and social change had advanced the most, post-democratic military
11
dictatorships had a very negative impact on the development of academic life, not to talk
about democracy and public debate.
As mentioned above, economic history in Latin America had always been very
much involved in current debates on development strategies and political involvement was
not unusual in academia. The dictatorships had thus a huge negative impact on academic
life in general, and particularly in the social sciences. The good side of the story, even if it
weighs much less than the negative, was that many scholars and young students had to go
into exile, thus favouring an increasing exchange with the international academic
community. This is important as it counteracted propensities among Latin Americans to
autonomous thinking and provincialism. Of course, academic life was not only weakened,
but heterodox thinking was often repressed at the universities, although it varied between
countries.
The Brazilian dictatorship, for instance, was the first of its kind and lasted for a
long period (from 1964 to the early 1980s). Many scholars went into exile (to Chile before
the State coup, then Mexico and many other countries in different continents). The
Brazilian dictatorship was a pioneer in implementing ambitious national postgraduate and
academic research programmes. A combination of uncontested hegemony and rapid
economic growth allowed for the expansion of research, even on heterodox lines. In
Argentina, Chile and Uruguay, however, the damage made by the new political regimes
was deeper. Mexico and Venezuela, on the contrary, were countries that attracted many
refugees from other Latin American countries, and they became strongly internationalised
academic milieus. After the State coup in Chile, ECLA survived as an island, with
significantly reduced activity and influence.
Jointly with the adversities imposed by the political context featured by
authoritarian regimes, the crisis of macro-theories that linked historical research with
development strategies, and the prevalence of neoclassical macroeconomic theory
introduced all the elements for the divorce between history and economics, and even
between economics and other social sciences. Economic historians of the Golden Age
regarded the New Economic History with a combination of interest and scepticism. The
American school, and more broadly quantitative methods, were discussed by Ruggiero
Romano (1972) and Marcello Carmagnani (1972), and later on by Cardoso & Pérez
12
Brignoli (1976). They welcomed the systematic use of quantitative data3, but they were
concerned about its perils, some of them especially important in the case of Latin
American economic history.
Firstly, the sources needed to make a rigorous use of quantitative methods were
hardly available. Secondly, not all of the central aspects which were relevant for the
comprehension of historical reality –even in the reduced field of economic history- could
be quantified. In their opinion, New Economic History had a tendency to ignore those
aspects. Thirdly, the use of standard economic theory and concepts were hardly useful for
the analysis of the Latin American economic past.
The tensions involved in the in the transplantation of the methods of the NEH to
Latin America were evident in the debate triggered by the publication, of An Economic
History of Colombia, 1845–1930, in 1971, a book written at the beginning of the 1960s by
the economist William Paul McGreevey as his PhD dissertation in the Massachusetts
Institute of Technology. McGreevey´s aim was to introduce cliometrics in Colombia, but
the result was exactly the opposite. In his book, McGreevey combined the use of
sophisticated statistical methods, with a poor knowledge of Colombian sources and a
simplistic theoretical approach grounded in neoclassical economics. The book led to a big
controversy. Colombian historians of the New History movement, -a group close to the
Annales School and British Marxism created in the 1960s and led by Jaime Jaramillo
Uribe- considered that the book was flawed: false assumptions led to false conclusions.
While some of the critics considered the author himself to be responsible for the errors,
others considered the problem laid in the application of cliometric methods and
neoclassical theory to every historical context (Rodríguez & Arévalo 1994; Meisel 2007)4.
3
The handbook written by Cardoso and Pérez Brignoli (1976) devoted many pages to teaching
quantitative methods like index numbers, trend-cycle decomposition, and even had an appendix that
introduced the reader to computers and punched cards. Also, in their view not all kinds of quantitative history
were the same. They distinguished between the French school of serial history, quantitive history a la
Kuznets, and the ‘new economic history’.
4
Even to Meisel, (2007) who lamented the slow diffusion of the NEH to Colombia, agrees that
McGreveey’s book had too many problems.
13
In the decades that followed, the Annales-school went through a process of splitting
and combination with postmodern approaches, which left the study of economic issues as
completely old-fashioned. As economics became more and more formal, general, and less
focused on historical changes, it became of less interest for historians, who tended to react
negatively to formalisation and abstract thinking. Among Marxists, confusion prevailed
and historians, trying to understand more and more concrete cases, increasingly protected
themselves behind the shelter of hard facts. Thus, a trend towards empirical research with
weak theoretical, methodological and comparative reflection developed hand in hand with
the increasing interest in local history, daily life, culture and so on. These two features did
not need to go hand in hand, but this was the prevailing trend in Latin America.
In regard to economists, at least in Latin America, the new wave of neoclassical and
monetary thinking did not stimulate the study of economic history. However, a new wave
of studies tried to show that Latin American backwardness was a problem that first
appeared due to import-substitution policies after the Great Depression, and that economic
performance prior to that had been very good. However, the big picture is that economists,
contrary to what happened during the Golden Age, became less interested in history and
more focused on the short-run and contemporary problems.
Within this context, some cores of economic history writings persisted. In Brazil,
one important research centre was the Department of Economics of the State University of
Campinas (Sao Paulo). Scholars as Joâo Manuel Cardoso de Mello, Wilson Cano, Wilson
Suzigan, Tamas Szmrecsányi, Fernando Novaes, Mario Posas and many others, made
important contributions in the fields of ‘late’ capitalist development, ‘early’ (pre-1930)
industrialisation, slave economy, and business history. Their research followed on the
Structuralist tradition, but was rather precocious in developing it in interaction with new
Post-keynessian, evolutionary and neo-Schumpeterian ideas, in line with what was later on
called Neo-Structuralism. In the 1990s a Master and a Doctoral programme in Economic
History were launched.
In Argentina the social sciences suffered a devastating attack during the 1970s. It
was not until the early 1980s that the situation started to revert. As for Brazil, its system of
postgraduate studies developed first in the late 1990s. Postgraduate programs in social
sciences developed slowly and in a loosely articulated way. Even if some regional efforts
were made, especially in Córdoba and Santa Fe, academic life was strongly concentrated in
14
Buenos Aires. The divorce between History and Economics showed in Argentina a more
profound ideological content. Mainstream economics had a much more powerful influence
in Argentina than in Brazil, and the economic historical bibliography written by
economists had a strong neo-classical inspiration, as evidenced, for example, in the works
of Díaz Alejandro, Roberto Cortés Conde, and more recently, Gerardo della Paolera and
Alan Taylor. On the other hand, historians still working on economic history issues
remained strongly committed to some type of Annales-like history writing, qualitatively
oriented and highly concentrated on agricultural history, labour movements and state
building. Dominated by left-wing thinking, each attempt to quantify economic issues was
immediately considered ideologically suspicious. The Chilean and Uruguayan cases, even
with subtle differences, developed similarly to the Argentine.
One important outcome of this period was that Latin American scholars hardly
produced any book or general study on the economic history of Latin America. This was in
sharp contrast with previous developments. Most projects on general Latin American
economic history were led by Anglophone scholars, with some exceptions.
The publication of the Cambridge History of Latin America in the mid-1980s
initiated a change in the way general works covering the whole Latin American region
were written. Since the mid-1980s, and until recently, the main general works on Latin
America were written in English first. Rosemary Thorp and Victor Bulmer-Thomas came
to be responsible for two of the most important comprehensive works which have been
published since then. The Economic History of Latin America since Independence by
Victor Bulmer-Thomas (Cambridge, 1994) is analytically strong and penetrating, and uses
a dualistic model to assess the performance of different Latin American countries in the
export-led era. Rosemary Thorp’s Progress, Poverty and Exclusion: an Economic History
of Latin America in the 20th Century (Inter-American Development Bank, 1998) is the
result of a research project financed by the Inter-American Development Bank, in which
more than thirty outstanding scholars were involved. Finally, in 2006, the Cambridge
Economic History of Latin America was edited by Victor Bulmer-Thomas, John
Coastworth and Roberto Cortés Conde (still not translated into Spanish). In short, it seems
that Latin American scholars were not, by themselves, producing as many comprehensive
works on Latin American economic history, and history in general.
15
4- A new generation of economic history writings in and on Latin
America since the 1990s
After what we can call a downward phase in Latin American economic history
during the 1980s, we can identify a phase of recovery in the late 1990s and a phase of
expansion in the recent decades. This upward trend is the result of many different factors.
Without any doubt, the comprehensive works on Latin American economic history
edited outside Latin America had an important impact on the region, revealed the
international interest on the topic and contributed with new lines of research. At the same
time, they demanded new inputs from scholars of the region. Thus, these works had what
we can call both backward and forward linkages.
A second factor that contributed to the development of economic history was the
changes in the political climate. Democratic consolidation in the region allowed for the
recovery of plural academic life, the free circulation of ideas, the return of many scholars
from exile, and the expansion of the educational system in general, with new research
centres, networks and postgraduate programmes. Furthermore, the access to new
technologies, as elsewhere, made it possible to process available data in different forms,
stimulating historical research. Moreover, the increasing opportunities for international
exchange opened up new possibilities and stimulated research. Besides that, the radical
changes in the patterns of development due to the so-called structural reforms, the high
volatility that still prevailed in the region and the combination of spasmodic growth and
deepened social inequality, regained interest on the study of long-term development
patterns and, in particular, the study of the now called first globalization boom.
While the neoclassical research agenda remained very active (relative prices,
globalization, income inequality), economic history research was also fuelled by the
development of new institutional economics, which often used Latin America as the
example of bad institutions and poor performance. Moreover, the development of NeoStructuralism and ECLAC´s recovery as an influential think tank in the region contributed
to the theoretical renewal of economic history writings. The new phase of expansion is
clearly noticed in the scholarly production and in institutional success.
Scholarly production made progress along very different lines. Without any doubt,
one of the most dynamic fields was quantitative economic history. New generations of
16
national accounts were produced, as well as important datasets on prices, wages, tariffs,
taxes, state expenditure, energy production and consumption, inequality, and more. On this
basis, comparative research has increased and performance is being assessed.
Institutional history made huge progress. Plenty of studies revisited old topics and
opened new ones, both during the colonial and independency period. Many national cases
are clearly documented and the links to modern theoretical discussions on legal systems,
property rights, liberal reforms and institutions (broadly speaking), are strong and fruitful.
Many authors have tackled labour relations, legal frameworks for the operation of
business, the creation of national states, the advance of the liberal reforms, the fiscal
structures, institutional instability, the use of money, and more. The programmes of the
Latin American Economic History Congresses (CLADHEs), is full of papers documenting
these trends. A particular line of institutional research is the one linking institutions and
technical change. This is particularly the case for the 20th century. While institutions have
been studied mainly within the Solowian framework, focusing on capital and human
capital accumulation, the Structuralist tradition has focused more on Schumpeterian
approaches to institutions.
Inequality was a central topic in the Structuralist and dependency approaches, both
in terms of the international and the domestic economy: the outflow of resources and the
concentration of property and income were considered to be permanent features of the
export-led model, having a strong negative impact on development. Interest in this topic
receded in the 1980s and 1990s. Perhaps due to the intense political debate over who gains
from the recent globalization experience, there has been a revival of historical interest in
income distribution during the last few years, both theoretically and empirically. A special
issue of the Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History was published, in
which different approaches were noticeable. While mainstream approaches focus mainly
on relative price movements as a result of market integration and disintegration
(Williamson), Bértola and co-authors stress the role played by the different social
structures, productive patterns and institutional frameworks (including international power
relations), to explain the outcomes of market integration in terms of inequality. Bértola
(2005), and Rodríguez Weber (2014) are examples of ambitious reconstruction of
historical data in terms of lung-run series, and interpretations that try to combine more
conventional tools of analysis and socio-institutional approaches, that can be labeled as
17
political economy approaches. While these works, especially that of Rodríguez Weber,
emphasize the role of colonial heritage in explaining structurally high inequality, contrary
to neo-institutional approaches, an important part of the study aims to explain historical
change, fluctuations in inequality trends, and the appearance of new actors and social
relations with different outcomes.
From a more quantitative point of view, (Bértola et al. 2010b, 2011), have
enhanced the discussion of human development with measures for inequality in the
distribution of the different components of the index. Latin American relative performance
looks significantly worse when these dimensions are taken into account.
Also within the Structuralist tradition, many studies revisited classical topics, such
as the features of the domestic productive structure, the constraints on the way in which
Latin America relates to the world economy, the role of the State through regulation and
through State-owned enterprises, the features of the agrarian sector and property
concentration, the financial crisis and the patterns of international capital movements, the
features of the national states and integration policies, and so on. Moreover,
entrepreneurial history made important progress, trying to tackle the problem of lack
entrepreneurial capacities in Latin America and to assess the role of Multinational
Enterprises.
Progress along these lines is documented by an important increase in publications.
National compilations, as the one edited by Sandra Kuntz in México, the one edited by
Jorge Gelman in Argentina, and the volumes edited by Banco de la República de Colombia
(by Meisel and Ramírez, and by Robinson and Urrutia), are good examples. New reviews
appeared, as América Latina en la Historia Económica, the Revista Uruguaya de Historia
Económica, together with increased interest in Latin America shown, for example, by the
Spanish Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic
History and Investigaciones en Historia Económica. Finally, two books on Latin American
economic history written by Latin American scholars came to light during the last few
years: Institucionalidad y Desarrollo Económico, edited by Luis Bértola and Pablo
Gerchunoff (2011), and The Economic Development of Latin America since Independence,
18
written by Luis Bértola and José Antonio Ocampo (2012)5. These two books reflect upon
the collective efforts by many scholars working on Latin America (Latin Americans or not)
in the recent decades that represent the recovery of old traditions mixed with new
theoretical and methodological developments. In any case, they represent the development
of Latin American capabilities to analyze the economic history of the region.
From the point of view of the content of economic history, we can say that it
closely followed the main trends in international economy history in its different versions.
However, as happened during the golden age, the efforts to combine theory building at a
meso-level with economic history analysis are still vibrant. Side by side with increasingly
professionalized economic history production, we can notice a process of institution
building.
Economic history is cultivated in both departments of history and of economics, or
development economics. There are more than a few postgraduate programs in economic
history. Besides the already mentioned of Universidad de Campinas, we have postgraduate
programmes in de University of San Paolo, University of Buenos Aires, in Universidad
Autónoma de México, and at the Universidad de la República, Uruguay. The latter, besides
its Master and Ph. D. Programmes, has organized Southern Hemisphere Summer Schools
annually, with the participation of students from different Latin American, European and
even African countries. Very important to the academic training of young scholars have
been also the Spanish universities, as well as Americans and the LSE.
We have now seven national economic history associations in the region
(Argentina, Brazil Chile, Colombia, México, Perú and Uruguay), besides one in the
Caribbean.
The Argentine Economic History Association (Asociación Argentina de Historia
Económica) is the oldest in the region and it is admirable that it has succeeded in
organising a National Congress every two years since the 1970s regardless of dramatic
political and economic changes. These congresses, especially in the 1990s, have attracted a
very wide range of scholars from different social sciences and have been held in many
5
Spanish edition by FCE, 2013, and Portuguese edition by Elsevier, forthcoming in 2014.
19
different cities of the Argentine interior, thus helping to strengthen local research groups.
The Brazilian, Mexican and Uruguayan associations were created in the early 1990s, while
the remaining four were created during the past couple of years, exemplifying the
expansion phase we talked about.
However, probably the main institutional success in the region is the organization
of the Latin American Economic History Congresses (CLADHE, for the Spanish acronym)
every two or three years .The first one was organized in Montevideo, in 2007 and the sixth
is to be held in Sao Pablo in 2016. About 400 hundred papers have been presented on
average in these congresses, with participants from many Latin American countries and
active participation of scholars from America and Europe. These congresses have
promoted the creation of important international networks which in turn stimulated the
development of comparative research. The congresses have attracted the participation of
many young scholars, decisive for the future development of economic history.
Another example of institutional progress was the move of the Latin American
Economic History Database from Oxford to Montevideo. Hopefully, the now called
MOxLAD will continue to reflect and promote quantitative economic history in the region,
and establish good interfaces with global databases.
5- Concluding remarks
During the recent decade economic history in Latin America exhibited a new wave
of expansion. It did not recover the central role it had during the Golden Age of the 1960s
and 1970s, but it is now an established field of research, with few but strong research
centres.
While economic history became more professional, it still seems to be very much
engaged in current debates on development patterns and prospects in the region. In spite of
the economic progress noticed during the last decade, as well as progress in many social
indicators and democratic consolidation in the region, Latin America still faces the
challenge to find a route to development. Economic history is still trying to shed light on
the processes that have clear continuities in the present. Therefore, topics such as the
origins and dynamics of inequality will remain on the agenda. The question about
specialization in primary production connecting historical experience with future
prospects, as well as the different attempts to produce changes in the productive structure
20
will re-emerge. Business history has still much to say about Latin American historical
performance. Growth sustainability today is fueling more and more studies on energy
consumption and environmental change from an historical perspective. Labor-market
studies, together with the challenges of the welfare states in different international
environments, is another strong point of the agenda. And, last but not least, institutional
research will continue to be a vibrant field of research with important contemporary
implications.
Hopefully, economic history will continue to find spaces in the academic milieu
where to develop strong research groups and teaching programs. An active participation in
international forums and networks will make sure that Latin American economic
historiography will continue to be global and learn from developments abroad. If research
is deeply rooted in domestic institutional environments and agenda, it will surely continue
in the good tradition of searching for proper answers to relevant questions for Latin
America.
21
6- References
Arcondo, A. (2003) ‘Ruggiero Romano y la historia económica colonial de América
Latina’, Cuicuilco 10 (29): 1-16
Assadourian, C. S. (1975) Modos de producción en América Latina, Buenos Aires,
Siglo Veintiuno Editores
Bértola 2005 “A 50 años de la Curva de Kuznets: Crecimiento y distribución del
ingreso en Uruguay y otras economías de nuevo asentamiento desde 1870”,
Investigaciones en Historia Económica
Bértola, L. and J. A. Ocampo, (2012) The Economic Development of Latin America
Since Independence, Oxford, Oxford University Press
Bértola, L. and P. Gerchunoff, (2011) Institucionalidad y desarrollo económico en
América Latina, Santiago de Chile, CEPAL
Bertola, L., Hernandez, M., Rodríguez Weber, J., & Siniscalchi, S. (2011) “Un siglo
de desarrollo humano y desigualdad”, ponencia presentada en las 5as ‘Jornadas de
Historia Económica’, Asociación Uruguaya de Historia Económica, Montevideo
Bértola, L., Castelnovo, C., Rodríguez Weber, J., Wilebald, H. (2010a) “Between the
colonial heritage and the first globalization boom: on income inequality in the
southern cone”, Revista de Historia Económica, v.: 28 2, pp. 307-348
Bértola, L., Camou, M., Maubrigades, S. and Melgar, N. (2010b), “Human
Development and Inequality in the Twentieth Century: The Mercosur Countries in a
Comparative Perspective” in: Salvatore, R., Coatsworth, J. H. y Challú, A. E. (Org.),
Living Standards in Latin American History: Height, Welfare and Development, 17502000, Cambridge, David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies, Harvard
University
Bonilla, H. (1972) ‘Introducción’, in H. Bonilla, (ed.) La historia económica en
América Latina. Situación y métodos, México, D.F., Secretaría de Educación Pública
Bulmer-Thomas V. (1994) The economic history of Latin America since
independence, Cambridge, New York, Cambridge University Press
Burga, M. (2005) La Historia y los historiadores en el Perú, Lima, UNMSM, Fondo
Editorial
Burke, P. (1990) The French historical revolution: the Annales school, 1929-89,
Stanford, Calif., Stanford University Press
22
Cardoso, F. E. and E. Faletto (1969), Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina:
Ensayo de interpretación sociológica, México, Siglo Veintiuno Editores
Cardoso, C. F. S. and H. Pérez Brignoli (1976)
:
introducción a los problemas, métodos y técnicas de la historia demográfica,
económica y social, Barcelona, Editorial Crítica
Cardoso, C. F. S. and H. Pérez Brignoli (1979) Historia económica de América
Latina, Barcelona, Editorial Crítica
Carmagnani, M. (1972), Metodología y técnicas para una historiografía económica
latinoamericana, in Bonilla, H. (ed.) La historia económica en América Latina.
Situación y métodos, México, D.F., Secretaría de Educación Pública
Furtado, C. (1969) La economía latinoamericana: desde la conquista ibérica hasta la
revolución cubana, México, Siglo Veintiuno Editores
Halperín Donghi, T. (1969) Historia contemporánea de América Latina, Madrid,
Alianza
Halperín Donghi, T. (1972) ‘Situación de la historia económica en Argentina’, in
Bonilla, H. (ed.) La historia económica en América Latina. Situación y métodos,
México, D.F., Secretaría de Educación Pública
Mariátegui, J. C. (1928) 7 Ensayos de Interpretación de la Realidad Peruana, Lima,
Biblioteca Amauta
Meisel, A. (2007) ‘Un balance de los estudios sobre historia económica de Colombia,
1942-2005’, in M. Urrutia, and J. Robinson, J. (eds.) Economía colombiana del siglo
XX: un análisis cuantitativo, Bogotá, Fondo de Cultura Económica - Banco de la
República
Rodríguez, O. (2005) El estructuralismo latinoamericano, México, Siglo Veintiuno
Editores - CEPAL
Rodríguez, O. and D. Arévalo, (1994) ‘La historiografía económica colombiana del
siglo XIX’ in B. Tovar Zambrano (ed.) La historia al final del milenio: ensayos de
historiografía colombiana y latinoamericana, Volumen 1, Bogotá, Universidad
Nacional de Colombia
Rodríguez Weber, J. E. (2014) “La Economía Política de la Desigualdad de Ingreso en
Chile, 1850-2009” PhD dissertation on Econoimc History, Economic and Social
History Program, Universidad de la República, Uruguay
23
Romano, R. (1972) ‘Conveniencias y peligros de aplicar los métodos de la “nueva
histórica económica”, in H. Bonilla, (ed.) La historia económica en América Latina.
Situación y métodos, México, D.F., Secretaría de Educación Pública
Sunkel, O. and P. Paz, (1970) El subdesarrollo latinoamericano y la teoría del
desarrollo, México, Siglo Veintiuno Editores
Thorp, R., (1998) Progress, poverty and exclusion: an economic history of Latin
America in the 20th century, Washington, D.C., Inter-American Development Bank
24
Descargar