Guilford Press Marx on Financial Intermediation: Lessons from the French "Crédit Mobilier" in the "New York Daily Tribune" Author(s): JOSEPH RICCIARDI Source: Science & Society, Vol. 79, No. 4 (OCTOBER 2015), pp. 497-526 Published by: Guilford Press Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/24585271 Accessed: 02-08-2021 02:30 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Guilford Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Science & Society This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Science & Society, Vol. 79, No. 4, October 2015, 497-526 o Marx on Financial Intermediation: Lessons from the French Crédit Mobilier in the New York Daily Tribune JOSEPH RICCIARDI* ABSTRACT: The role of financial intermediaries in economic devel opment can be clarified by examining Marx's contributions to an old debate among economic historians regarding the role of joint stock investment banking and, in particular, the rise of the French Crédit Mobilier, in French economic development. Marx's account of the Crédit Mobilier, in a series of articles written for the New York Daily Tribune during the 1850s, contains the oudines of a theory of the potentially destabilizing role of financial intermediaries in economic development. Five propositions regarding financial intermediaries (Fis) in development emerge: First, Fis promote the multiplication of financial claims to social wealth beyond any conceivable basis for their realization in production. Second, Fis immobilize and misallocate capital. Third, the lender of last resort function of the Central Bank is necessarily ineffective in confronting crises of Fis. Fourth, Fis accelerate the restructuring and concentration of capi talist property. Finally, Fis play an explicit political role in "buying time"in the context of class struggle, deferring conflict to a later date. Introduction tional capital markets, sustained during the "lost" decade of FINANCIAL PUBLIC, the 1980s, theTURBULENCE financial contagion of theIN 1990s, and renewed private, and interna * The author wishes to thank Harry Cleaver, William Darityjr., the late Laurence Moss, Michele Naples, and John Parsons for detailed comments on earlier versions of this paper. The author is also grateful to the late C. P. Kindleberger for assistance on matters of French financial history. Finally, thanks to the Science & Society reviewers for their painstaking scrutiny to improve the argument. Errors that may remain are the responsibility of the author alone. 497 This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 498 SCIENCE 6= SOCIETY with global financial collapse in 2008 (Bear Stearns, Lehman Broth ers, AIG) and 2010 (EU sovereign debt, Greece, Italy, et al), presse economists of all persuasions to reexamine the role of money and finance in the macroeconomy. Worn explanations from economis have been challenged by new frameworks advanced by geographers (Harvey, 2011), philosophers (Caffentzis, 2013) and anthropologist (Graeber, 2011 ). This paper examines the destabilizing role of fina cial intermediaries in the macroeconomy by revisiting Marx's analy sis of the rise of the French Crédit Mobilier as the first appearance of investment banking in nascent European capitalism. Ex post, Mar contributes to an old debate among economic historians: Did the ris of joint stock investment banking really matter in French economi development? Did the financial innovation of the Crédit Mobilier serve to more efficiently allocate capital, permitting France to break throug its metallist financial backwardness and fuel French industrialization some 50 years after Britain?1 Or did the Crédit Mobilier inherently desta bilize French accumulation, fueling the speculation that ultimately produced the global financial collapse of 1857? It was the October 1987 New York stock market crash that first con centrated attention on "bubbles" in the modern mainstream econom ics literature.2 Against Post-Keynesian claims that financial markets are inherently unstable and fuel speculative distortions (asset-prices diverging from fundamentals), orthodox economists affirmed that financial markets are "informationally efficient." The implication: Bubbles can exist where asset prices diverge from equilibrium values, but such deviations can not be systematically sustained or exploited 1 The Crédit Mobilier was founded by Issac and Emile Péreire in 1852. It was one of the most important financial institutions of the 19th Century. The Péreire brothers, imbued with St. Simonist doctrine, leveraged their investment bank to finance enormous rail, industrial, and public works projects on a global scale, competing with the commercial banking interests of the Rothschilds. Note: this should not be confused with the U. S. Credit Mobilier, a con struction company founded in 1863 by officers and large stockholders of the Union Pacific railway. The latter earned its notoriety by engaging in large-scale graft involving leading members of the Republican party, a scandal that was revealed by The Sun newspaper of New York in 1872. 2 See the Symposium on "Bubbles" (Stiglitz, 1990) and Tirole, 1989. For recent orthodox theorization on bubbles and financial crises see Brunnermeier and Oehmke, 2012. For a Marxist perspective, see Parsons, 1988, who emphasizes the positive effects of developed financial markets in the coordination of productive activity. He is critical of those he terms "bubble theorists" who equate modern financial markets with gambling. Parsons recognizes the potential for economic crises generated by these markets, but does not address the predisposition to crises associated with the autonomous drive of financial accumulation to outstrip its basis in the production of real wealth. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 499 for profit by speculators. Orthodoxy concluded that since marke incorporate all unanticipated information into asset prices, bubb can exist and be rational as a consequence of numerous "friction but financial markets in themselves present no inherent foundat or predisposition to speculation.3 Marx's commentary on the role of French investment banking in spawning the recurrent crises of the 1800s provides useful insight in the specific role of financial intermediaries in the process of capitali crises. In what follows, I examine Marx's views on financial inter diation developed in a series of articles written for the New York Da Tribune during the 1850s, which have received little attention4 and often dismissed as Marx's journalistic work for hire.5 The articles re Marx's real-time analysis of the rise of private joint-stock banking a an innovation in French finance, highlighting its role in simulta ously accelerating industrialization and promoting financial colla Five distinct contributions to understanding the specific role financial intermediaries in capitalist crises emerge from Marx's exam nation of the Credit Mobilier. First, financial intermediaries promot the multiplication of financial claims to social wealth beyond an basis for their realization in production. Financial intermediaries thu predispose the economy to debt-deflation crises due to the driv force of speculation in the normal operations of finance. In contr with the post-Keynesians, however, Marx argues that the heart of th debt-deflation crisis is a crisis of imposing work. This means that su cessful collateralization is contingent on convincing debt-holders capital's capacity to discipline labor and annex surplus value at a futu date — a capacity which is inherently uncertain. Second, Marx suggests that financial intermediaries immobili and misallocate capital. Such misalignments occur across product 3 This specification of the informational efficiency of financial markets is the cornerston the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. 4 One brilliant exception is the piece by Sergio Bologna (1974). It is interesting to note even in such a developed theoretical treatment on finance as Hilferding's Finance Cap no mention whatsoever appears regarding Marx's NYDTarticles on the Crédit Mobilier. F comprehensive discussion of Marx's "career" at the Tribune and his rivalry with Henry Ca see Perelman, 1987. 5 Marx and Engels were not immune from "work for hire." Both contributed entries t New American Cyclopedia (New York, 1858-63), a 16-volume dictionary, which Engels refe to as a "purely commercial matter, nothing else." The numerous articles written for the York Daily Tribune, however, where Marx served as a European correspondent, were wi read, with a circulation of 200,000, and influenced U. S. economist Henry Carey. During U. S. Civil War, Marx devoted his articles increasingly to American affairs (Morias, 1948 This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms SCIENCE àf SOCIETY 500 sectors {e.g., agriculture vs. industry), within production (labor vs capital), over time (present vs. future), as well as disrupting the c culation of value over the various circuits of capital. Third, Marx argues that Central Bank efforts to intervene as the "lender of last resort" prove ineffective in the face of financial crises since the Central Bank merely substitutes the fictitious capital of the state for the bad debt of private capital. Fourth, Marx argues th financial intermediaries accelerate the restructuring and concent tion of capitalist property. Finally, Marx argues that financial intermediaries play an explicit political role in the context of the class struggle. French finance capit was mobilized to "buy time" in order to consolidate power and strangle the February Revolution, as well as to provide support for Napoleon program for "Imperial Socialism." Each of these five propositions is examined in detail below to suggest an outline of Marx's thinking on financial intermediation Caution must be exercised with any attempt to formulate genera principles from the particular experience of the Crédit Mobilier. None theless, Marx's rich observations on the role of investment bankin in French development and crises offer a unique view of the overa dynamics of accumulation, seen specifically from the perspective finance. I. FINANCIAL INTERMEDIARIES, SPECULATION, AND FICTITIOUS VALUES: THE CRÉDIT MOBILIER AND THE LOGIC OF DEBT-DEFLATION Conventional wisdom has long been that the British significant stripped the French in economic development in the 18th and centuries, because French financial institutions lagged behind British counterparts by 30 years in joint-stock banking and ov years in central bank formation and policy (Kindleberger,1983 nomic historians since the 1950s (e.g., Cameron, 1961; Gerschen 1962) have suggested that the Crédit Mobilier was the most impor example of a financial intermediary engaged in financing Fren nomic development. Massive public works and long-term invest projects were facilitated by the Crédit Mobilier's role in restructu French capital markets — intermediating funds from savers to inve through indirect security issue. This was presented as "democra This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 501 credit" and showcasing economic development through the const tion of urban centers. Marx's chronicle of the Crédit Mobilier provides us with a different picture of the role of financial intermediaries in capitalist accumulation — a view unparalleled in his more traditionally cited economic writ ings. Marx's New York Daily Tribune series examines the destabilizing role of the Crédit Mobilier and of capitalist finance generally in pro voking economic crises. For Marx, as with the economic historians, "finance matters," but not because of the economies associated with an improved intertemporal allocation of capital. It is the distortions in capital allocation resulting from speculation that concern him. Between June 1856 and December 1857 Marx wrote 58 articles for the New York Daily Tribune. Of these, 13 directly addressed mat ters concerning the Crédit Mobilier, which, Marx argued, "presents itself as one of the most curious economical phenomena of our epoch" (MECW, XV, 10). Early neoclassical formulations, e.g., Tobin (1968), argue the principal raison d'etre of a financial system is ensur ing that risk bearing is distributed in accordance with "tastes" for risk-taking. Financial intermediaries reduce risk and thus augment real economic activity by promoting investment that would other wise be rationed due to a misallocation of risk. It happens that Issac Péreire (1854) wrote of a similar sort of "risk-pooling" and "risk reduction through portfolio diversification" in his promotion of the Crédit Mobilier in the 1850s. Marx, however, viewed the essence of such portfolio diversifica tion on the part of financial intermediaries not as risk-reduction, but as speculation: We have heard, from Issac Péreire, that one of the mysteries of the Crédit Mobilierwas the principle of multiplying its action and diminishing its risks by embarking in the greatest possible variety of enterprises, and withdrawing from them in the shortest possible time. Now, what does this mean when divested of the flowery language of St. Simonism? Subscribing for shares to the greatest extent, in the greatest number of speculations, realizing the premiums, and getting rid of them as fast as it can be done. Stockjobbing, then, is to be the base of the industrial development, or rather all industrial enterprise is to become the mere pretext of stock-jobbing. (MECW, XV, 20.) For Marx, investment banks drive industrial accumulation into the hands of stockjobbers. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 502 SCIENCE & SOCIETY Financial intermediaries are predisposed to excessive risk-tak in their investment activities due to the profit logic of their nor operations. For the Crédit Mobilier, its nominal source of profits deri simply from the spread between the rate of interest payable on deposits and debentures, and the interest receivable on the secur in which it subsequently invested. In order to maximize this inte rate spread, the Crédit Mobilier sought, on the one hand, to in the capital realized from the issue of its debentures in projects promised the highest returns, but typically involved higher risk substantial price variability. The incentives to this sort of risk-takin were heightened by the fact that shareholders "shared" in all t risks of the Crédit Mobilier, but were entitled only to a fixed return its debentures (MECW, XV, 23) .6 The Crédit Mobiliers function a intermediary was to acquire other people's capital and to stimula flurry of speculation in securities trading on the Bourse. Profit maximization, on the other hand, dictated strategies f driving up the value of its own debentures so as to augment the nom nal value of the Crédit Mobilier's command over loanable capital for given debt issue. Utilizing its privileged position with respect to state — a government charter affording it a premium on its securit — the Crédit Mobilier sought to drive up the price of its securities i subsequent trade and issue. By driving the prices of its paper a from the value of its fundamentals, the investment house aimed further leverage its position in the market to reap speculative retur The scheme was to financial intermediaries whatjohn Law's schem was to commercial banking: What are the means proposed to enable it thus to "multiply its action" "diminish its risks"? ... The Crédit Mobilier, being a privileged company certain that the shares of any new enterprise started by it will, on the fir emission, fetch a premium in the market. It has learned this much fr Law, to allot its own shareholders the new shares at par, in proportion to t 6 Note the parallel to Keeton's (1984) argument that Fis take on higher levels of risk th socially optimal due to the moral hazard problem associated with fixed premium dep insurance. 7 Law, a Scottish economist, established theBanque Générale in France in 1716. He advocated stimulating industry by extending credit. The bank leveraged its privileged government back ing to promote the unbridled credit expansion that provided the fuel for Law's swelling of shares in the Mississippi Company in Louisiana. Share prices skyrocketed, then crashed in 1720, implicating Law as the architect of the great Mississippi Bubble. His Banque Générale subsequently collapsed, throwing the French economy into chaos. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 503 number of shares they hold in the mother-society. The profit thus insured them acts, in the first place, on the value of the shares of the Crédit Mobili itself, while their high range, in the second place, insures a high value the new shares to be emitted. In this manner the Crédit Mobilier obtains com mand over a large portion of the loanable capital intended for investment in industrial enterprises. (MECW, XV, 20.) Marx argued that rising securities prices were a prerequisite to supporting a climate of speculation upon which the survival of the Crédit Mobilier depended. By monopolizing what were formerly the separate actions of individual private moneylenders, the Crédit Mobilier "worked" both sides of the market. It drove up the value of its securi ties and simultaneously collected promoter's profits, by "constantly speculating for its own account on the fluctuations of the very same securities, on their fall as well as their rise" (MECW, XV, 276). Marx also identified the importance of turnover in the activities of the Crédit Mobilier. On the one hand, profits derived from the differ ential between the interest payable on the long-term industrial paper it purchased and the interest receivable by "repackaging" this paper and issuing its own liabilities of shorter term and smaller denomina tion. On the other hand, an increased velocity of turnovers in its purchases and repackaging or reselling of primary industrial issues also accounted for major accretions to profits. Marx probed further to examine the impact of speculation on the solvency, liquidity, and capital adequacy of financial institutions. First, he argued that the increased risk composition of the bank's portfolio resulting from speculation posed a threat to solvency.8 Second, Marx argued that a false appearance of liquidity resulted from the bank's power to issue debt and thus control and accumulate sums of capi tal far beyond its own initial capitalization. Lastly, capital adequacy assumed a new dimension in the case of financial intermediaries whose capital consists not of hard cash or tangible wealth, but merely the paper representatives of industrial capital. For the Crédit Mobilier, survival demanded capital market inter ventions utilizing leverage to exploit asymmetries in power and infor mation; i.e., to "circulate" capital in a manner that simultaneously 8 Here, poor earnings performance on the bank's income earning assets can result in a situation where receipts plus cash inflows fall short of the bank's payment commitments. Insolvency results when such a negative cash flow exhausts the bank's capital. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 504 SCIENCE & SOCIETY redistributed capital in the organization's favor. Efficiency in "win ning" such a zero-sum game rested principally in wielding the market power secured by debt issue; i.e., attaching other people's claims to the revenue streams of industrial capital. Capital formation thus move beyond the scale of individual advances characteristic of the world o self-finance. Contrary to the neoclassical world of McKinnon (1973 however, where "overcoming the barrier of self-finance" is growth pro moting, Marx argues that this sort of capital formation fuels fictitious capital accumulation and predisposes the economy to financial crisi Marx focused particular attention on the power of financial inter mediaries to issue debt and on their need to exercise this power. Fo the Crédit Mobilier, it meant the power to borrow up to ten times its own capital through the issue of its own debentures. He argued: The exceptional character of its profits results from the enormous disproportio between its capital and its operations. That disproportion ... form(s) ... th organic law of its existence. If the disproportion ... were to disappear, th Crédit Mobilier would not dwindle to a common banking house, but would miserably break down. (MECW, XV, 271.)9 By definition, financial intermediaries "intermediate" through the issue of indirect securities, repackaging the primary debt issue of ultimate borrowers into liabilities whose maturity, denomination, and risk composition are more in line with the preferences of ultimate lenders. Marx argued, however, that this maturity transformation pro cess was built on a shaky foundation of fictitious capital. The sourc of instability is the bank's power to issue debt as a means of raisin capital. This power affords the bank command over other people's capital in addition to the command over idle savings. This capital, however, is not backed by the tangible wealth-producing capacity o industrial capital, but merely by the paper representatives of the value 9 Cameron (1961), as did Marx (MECW, XV, 274-77), attributes the demise of the Crédi Mobilier to the inability of the Pereires to grab hold of sufficient funds through debt issue Cameron writes: "The Pereires' original plan counted on the issue of the Crédit Mobilier' own bonds to bring in most of the resources for these operations. Unfortunately, they had to operate almost entirely without the assistance of this most powerful instrument. Cameron notes that in the early history of the Crédit Mobilier interest rates were abnormall high, which rendered bond issue prohibitively expensive. Cameron highlights the ongoing "guerilla warfare" between the Crédit Mobilier and the Bank of France in conjunction with the Rothschild empire who continually intervened to prevent th e Crédit Mohilier fro m makin its fiduciary money issue. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 505 of industrial capital. Marx described the Crédit Mobiliers debentu as such a form of fictitious value: A paper money of its own invention; payable at very long dates; based, not on the capital of the company, but on the securities for which it would be exchanged ... such an issue of fiduciary money the Crédit Mobilier calls aug menting its capital; common people are more likely to call it augmenting its debts. (MECW, XV, 275.) In this fashion the Crédit Mobilier manufactured fictitious value. The power to issue its own paper was the power to monetize debt. It stood between savers and investors, borrowing funds from the public against its own paper, which was issued on the basis of its intentions to make future purchases of industrial paper out of its borrowings. Marx argued that this organization of capital had profound desta bilizing effects. First, while Crédit Mobilier debentures earned a fixed yield on an aggregate of paper secured by a capital that was nominally of the same amount, the realizable value of this capital was contingent upon the quotations of the Bourse. When security prices inflated, so did Crédit Mobilier profits. However, when security prices fell, Marx argued, the threat of bankruptcy raised its head as the nominal value of the "paper capital" that investors could "grab at" fell below the value of their claims outstanding. These devaluations of capital formed the basis of liquidity panics and runs. In such events, the only backing the bank could offer was its paltry capital in conjunction with a sum of industrial paper whose nominal value could vanish in an instant when liquidated in the throes of such a panic. The holders of bank liabilities can always expect to "share" in these losses, but not in the gains of the bank's speculative activities. Second, Marx argued that the power to generate fictitious cap ital has negative impacts on aggregate accumulation through the decapitalization of productive industry in order to fuel the spectacle of gambling. He wrote: Upon this operation of turning a great part of the national capital from productive industry to unproductive gambling, the Crédit Mobilier rests its main claim to the gratitude of the nation. Louis Napoleon, indeed, derives an immense support from Messrs. Péreire & Co. Not only do they impart ficti tious value to the Imperial funds, but they are constantly fostering, drilling, This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 506 SCIENCE & SOCIETY propping, propagating that spirit of gambling which forms the vital principle of the present empire. (MECW, XV, 276.) The point is not unlike Keynes' view that capitalist finance promote speculation at the expense of enterprise. In Marx's view, however, the crucial problem is that "paper rep resentatives" of industrial capital — i.e., the various industrial secur ties that comprise the "capital" of financial institutions — assume an independent dynamic of their own, entirely disengaged from th accumulation of real productive capital. Financial claims circulate according to the circuit of interest-bearing capital — M-M' — in the fantastic world in which money appears simply to breed mor money. In such a world financial accumulation is driven forward b speculation with no regard to the real production of wealth. Whe financial accumulation is driven beyond its basis for realization in real production, financial crises emerge. Thus the cycle: the ficti tious capital of financial intermediaries forms a precipice of debt that fuels speculative financial accumulation which ultimately outruns real accumulation and collapses, resulting in a harsh deflation tha devalues capital, destroys fictitious claims to wealth, and bankrupt the holders of such capital. What Marx saw in the Crédit Mobilier were the seeds of the classic "debt-deflation" crisis.10 The analysis, however, went deeper than the relationship between prices and debt. Marx linked the fictitious nature of the capital characteristic of financial institutions to the problem of commanding surplus labor in the circuit of industrial capital. This relation between the money form and labor is examined below. The Finance of Debt-Deflation and the Imperative of Surplus Labor Financial accumulation proceeds on the basis of financial flows, which take the form of interest-bearing capital (M-M'). The accumu lation of industrial capital, on the other hand, proceeds on the basis of the pure exercise of command over the conditions of production 10 There is a long-standing literature on debt-deflation crises, though typically dated substan tially after Marx's time. Irving Fisher (1933) coined the term "debt-deflation" in his article of the same name. Much of this analysis was "pilfered," however, from the work of Thorstein Veblen (1904) on "Loan Credit." Keynes also advanced the analytics of "debt-deflation" as did Minsky, 1982; Kindleberger, 1978; and Davidson, 1978. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 507 and the imposition of surplus labor. To the degree industrialists on external finance, they can attempt to extend their command productive capital and labor to expand their operations. Marx arg however, that the loans made to industry by financial intermedia have no backing in realized production and are advanced only the anticipation of the realization of the products of future labo industry. Yet in spite of this, financial institutions continue to rega such loans as assets. Marx argued that the command over the n conditions of production afforded by the extension of finance capita is not secured until the realization of surplus labor from the new pr ductive operations validates both the claim to future income associat with the financial instrument as well as the return associated with the accumulation of industrial capital. Until such validation occurs, the capital involved is fictitious: The financial capital, because it represents a claim to values which have not been newly produced; the industrial capital, because it represents an advance of merely the promise of future value and not the advance of previously realized value from a prior period of production. Marx claimed that the paper held by the Crédit Mobilier as its "capital" was of no intrinsic value, nor was the fixed capital it repre sented. Fixed capital has no use-value as an article of consumption, and therefore has no value outside of its capacity to absorb living labor. As a result, the securities held by the Crédit Mobilier as capital could only lay claim to the future values produced through the mobi lization of living labor to produce surplus value in conjunction with fixed capital. In the absence of such command over labor, the paper representatives of this capital amount to merely so much worthless paper. Marx argued that this did not stop the banks from promoting the accumulation of fictitious capital and the layering of debt. Despite the fact that the real physical capital claimed by the bank's paper does not circulate and possesses no real value outside of its capacity to extract surplus labor — the first condition for it to possess any value at all — the paper representatives of this capital circulate with a life of their own and are transformed into so much money-capital when placed as " Crédit Mobilier" debentures. The liquidity generated is advanced once again as money-capital in industrial loans; i.e., further purchases of industrial paper, which, in turn, are further capitalized. A fundamental question arises with such a circuit: Does the money value generated out of claims to fixed capital, when subsequently This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 508 SCIENCE à? SOCIETY loaned out, serve as an advance of capital, or does it merely circula as revenue? From the point of view of the individual financial int mediary the money loaned counts as an asset upon which it expects to make a return. This return accrues as interest, the payment of which is associated with the command over the income streams of other economic agents that results from the pure ownership of capital on the part of the intermediary. The interest paid, however, must origi nate as a deduction from the surplus value produced by the borrower who must have mobilized labor productively — or else suffer a loss. From the vantagepoint of accumulation at the level of society as a whole, however, the advanced interest-bearing capital realizes itself as capital only to the degree an imposition of surplus labor is achieved that would not otherwise occur in its absence. Such newly created surplus value must be "shared" between both industrial and financial capitalists in proportions corresponding to their relative economic power. If, however, the payment of interest were the result of the liquidation of borrower assets as opposed to the creation of new values, then the effect of the loaned interest-bearing capital would be to merely transfer ownership of existing values from borrower to lender. In such a case, the money-capital is invested in appropriation and not accumulation. The circulation of value in this circumstance appears as a redistribution of money or the circulation of money as revenue and not a circulation of money as capital.11 Marx argued that the generation of fictitious values may occur even if surplus labor is imposed in the final instance as a result of the mobilization of idle capital; i.e., upon the successful completion of the circuit of productive capital initiated by the mobilization of previously idle money capital. Since the financial system is predisposed to gener ate financial claims beyond their basis for realization in production, financial accumulation proceeds at the expense of real production. 11 The distinction between the circulation of money as money (revenue) and the circulation of money as capital is an important one in Marx's work. The advance of money as money refers to the circulation of money in its role as a pure medium of exchange — for the execution of transactions. The advance of money as capital, however, refers to money's role in securing command over surplus labor and the realization of surplus value on a sum of money-capital advanced. In his later work in Volume III of Capital, Marx argued that financial crises are associated with the collapse of the circuit of money as capital into the simple circulation of money as medium of exchange. While ex ante such claims were advanced as capital, ex post they have merely recirculated the existing stock of values. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 509 Financial intermediaries not only create fictitious values, but their nature engage in a layering of fictitious values. Even the l money-capital employed by individual financial intermediaries, M noted, is built on a layering of the debt of the intermediaries th selves. The liabilities issued to raise this loan capital are secured o against the expected future realized values of the investment project which are yet to be financed by these very same prospective fut loans. The shareholders and creditors of the intermediary, therefore hold claims to the capital and future revenues of the intermed which at the same time give rise to the set of claims on labor and ne means of production exercised by the intermediary's industrial cl borrowers.12 Time is of the essence in all these relationships. Time must se rate attempts by the different wealth-holders to exercise the variou "duplicate" claims at the same moment. Until wealth is newly produc through the mobilization of living labor and the imposition of surpl labor, the financial intermediary accomplishes nothing except multiplication of paper claims to real values, which are beyond h of realization in the aggregate. Thus, where financial intermedia are present, holders of financial instruments must be satisfied twice First, the intermediary's claim on the surplus value of the indust borrower must be realized. Then, the shareholders and creditors the intermediary must be satisfied by means of a further deduc from this surplus value, which has been realized through the suc ful completion of the circuit of interest-bearing capital on the p of the intermediary. Marx emphasized that successful completion of the circuit o interest-bearing capital, M-M', presupposes the successful impo tion of surplus labor in the circuit of productive capital. Witho this, financial crises are immanent and capital is devalued — th accumulation of capital is reduced to the mere appropriation of ot people's capital and the existing stock of values is redistributed. I this link between the fictitious capital of financial intermediaries an the imposition of surplus labor in the sphere of industrial capital th formed the core of Marx's analysis of the debt-deflation crises in ent in financial intermediation. 12 In this respect Kindleberger's notion of speculation being something akin to "selling the same horse twice" (Kindleberger, 1978) is apropos to Marx's discussion of the link between speculation and fictitious capital. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms SCIENCE & SOCIETY 510 II. THE CRÉDIT MOBILIER AND THE IMMOBILIZATION OF CAPITAL In his November 26, 1856 article entitled, "The Economic Cr France," Marx (MECW, XV, 130-5) develops a second line o ment regarding the Crédit Mobilier: that normal operations imm rather than mobilize the circulation and accumulation of ca Marx suggests that the routine functioning of financial capital d the allocation of capital, both within the firm and with respect macro-composition of sectoral demand, which immobilizes cap inevitably renders continued reproduction of the existing pro capital impossible. As suggested by the very name of the institution, the P brothers envisioned the central function of the Crédit Mobilier to be the mobilization of capital. Through the issue of its indirect securities, the Crédit Mobilier sought to monetize France's tangible wealth and so mortgage French capital in order to conduct its lending activities abroad. The Péreires argued that the "mobile assets" — i.e., the shares and annuities that comprised its invest ments in joint-stock enterprises — made up the collateral for Crédit Mobilier debentures in the same way that mortgaged property or "fixed assets" secured the mortgage bonds issued by the Credit Fon der. While these "mobile assets" served as bank capital, they also acted to "free up" surplus commodity capital and fixed capital by "monetizing" them and recirculating these values as fictitious loan capital abroad. Emile Péreire boasted: "France . . . must sell its capital, its credit, and the science of its engineers as well as its machines, its textiles, and its articles of taste to those who can and will pay for them. ... I believe I have done a more useful and more moral [m'c] thing by promoting the Swiss, Spanish, Russian, and Austrian railways than if I had undertaken the Graissessac railway" (quoted in Cameron, 1961, 148).13 Péreire viewed the nation's capital as a "commodity" that could be sold profitably by monetizing the national wealth and loaning it at interest. 13 Péreire argued that foreign rail investments securitized by national capital would prove more productive than Napoleonic financing of the Graissessac Railroad, which (when completed, in 1858) transformed the small artisanal mining concessions of southern France into a major regional supplier of coal to the Mediterranean. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 511 Marx attacked Péreire's argument: The tendency [of the Crédit Mobilier] is to fix capital, not mobilize it. What it mobilizes is only the titles of property. The shares of the companies started by it are, indeed, of a purely floating nature, but the capital which they represent is sunk. The whole mystery of the Crédit Mobilier is to allure capital into industrial enterprises, where it is sunk, in order to speculate on the sale of the shares created to represent that capital. This explains the curious phenomenon that while the shares of the Crédit Mobilier are continually falling on the Bourse, its action is continually extending over Europe. (MECW, XV, 133, emphasis added.) In Marx's view, what financial intermediaries mobilize are paper claims to social wealth. These claims are mobilized precisely by immo bilizing the movement of capital in general. In order to circulate and therefore speculate on these paper representatives, real capital values must be "fixed" in the tangible form of fixed capital. This fixed capi tal serves as the collateral for the securities and the resultant mass of fictitious values that is generated through the advance of credits on its behalf. Thus, financial intermediaries "fix" liquid capital in bursts of speculative investment in productive capital — plant and equipment — in order to collateralize and monetize this capital for yet further lending and fixing. The neoclassical view (e.g., Mishkin, 2010; Wood, 1981) is that financial intermediaries promote growth by realizing investment opportunities that would otherwise be rationed due to lack of funds and/or the higher cost of securing funds on an individual basis. By improving the allocative efficiency of capital markets, financial inter mediaries ensure the optimal allocation of savings to ultimate users of funds, thereby maximizing the flexibility and mobility of capital.14 Opposed to this view, Marx argued that financial intermediaries promote distortions in the allocation of productive capital. These distortions, moreover, are a direct outcome of the normal opera tions of precisely the same efficient capital markets. In competitive and unregulated financial markets, where financial intermediaries are permitted to develop in response to existing market frictions, it is only "titles to property" that are traded in the circuit of interest bearing capital — not the real physical capital itself. While financial 14 The idea is not new. It was Smith who argued that the banking system constitutes a "waggon way" for economic development. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 512 SCIENCE & SOCIETY intermediaries mobilize these paper claims to real values in the circu of interest-bearing capital, the real capital underlying these clai remains immobile. Nonetheless, the real physical capital must be ent to serve as collateral for the mass of paper trading that takes pl overhead. The result is that although capital markets are "efficient" the transaction of paper claims to capital (i.e., in the sense of a r generalization of security prices for securities of the same qualit the underlying allocation of productive capital that emerges is of suboptimal and unstable. Savers do not want to hold real capital, because they either lack t necessary money-capital to own it or the knowhow or will to ope it. Financial intermediaries do not care to hold real capital, as th prime interest is in speculation. Profitable speculation on holdi and reselling real fixed capital assets is especially difficult, given rapid depreciation of fixed capital that comes with both technologic revolutions and physical decay. On the one hand, paper securities preserve the flexibility of capi by remaining perpetually outside of production and uncommitted to cific use-values (Harvey, 1982, 266). It is essential that capital rem fluid to respond spatially and sectorally to working-class initiatives production, as well as to the changing compositions of consumpt demand that devalue capital and so ruin its owners. On the other han this "mobility" of capital in its money value form is only apparent. circulation of capital as a whole must include the metamorphosis capital values into commodity-capital and productive-capital. Th fantasy of interest-bearing capital is the appearance that the a mulation of capital can proceed entirely within the confines of circuit of money-capital. Marx argued that the imperative of production inevitably c fronts the fantasy of financial capital. To receive interest, lenders m sacrifice the flexibility of their money-capital for a specified period time. During this time money must enter the sphere of product at which point that sum of value becomes tied down to the spec use-values comprising the elements of production. To the degree duction is successful and surplus labor realized, the newly produ values might, indeed, support the paper claims of interest-bear capital circulating overhead. There is the danger, however, that loaned money-capital may simply be transformed into the commodit hoards of speculators attempting to drive prices above values and th This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 513 force an appropriation of existing values that exceeds the outstanding interest commitments of these merchant-capital speculators. In ad tion, there is always the danger that the real productive investmen of industrial capital are simply not profitable. One problem that arises is the coordination of the amount of time lenders are willing to part with their money-values at a give price (interest) and the amount of time borrowers require to real the production of the augmented sum of values at a given retur and efficiency in imposing work in production. Coordinating thes exchanges is the objective of the capital market. But, at its root l the contradiction that the greater the advance of interest-bearin capital achieved to extend the flexibility and spectacular character capital accumulation, the greater the necessity to commit this capi to specific use-values which constrain and impede the flexibility a coordinating powers of capital as a whole. Once again, the logic of financial accumulation assumes a life o its own that fails to ensure that the underlying conditions of real pro duction will guarantee the future surplus value necessary to effect th wealth transfers essential to motivate interest-bearing capital. Und these circumstances a great portion of financial accumulation is merel the accumulation of bad debt which is at the same time the failure to secure command over future surplus labor in production. What appears initially as simply the "mismanagement" of the loan-portfolio in the face of "uncertainty" is, in fact, the loss or absence of command over labor. From the perspective of capital, the loss of command is the result of the diversion of capital from real accumulation to financial accumulation, as well as the disarticulation of the financial and pro ductive circuits of capital that occurs with the circulation of fictitious values. In part, it is the mismanagement of the financial capitalist who fails in "pushing debt" to determine that the appropriate condi tions of production are in place to provide the means of repayment for outstanding loans. More fundamentally, it is the sheer inability to harness working-class refusal and impose surplus labor. It is true that industrial production by its nature requires that capi tal be "fixed" in plant and equipment which demands the advance of money-capital over the lifetime of the fixed capital. Marx points out, however, that investment banks engaged in short-run profit maximiz ing behavior in the market for long-term securities tend to promote the sinking of fixed capital to a degree that is wholly out of proportion This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 514 SCIENCE 6J5 SOCIETY to the funds made available for the working capital necessary to oper ate the installed plant. In addition, fixed capital is advanced to an extent that would exceed the existing limits to demand, if the work ing capital were available to operate at capacity production. Marx noted that this asymmetric "fixing" of capital is peculiar to financial intermediaries engaged in long-term investment banking: The Crédit Mobilier fixes actually floating capital. Railway shares ... may be very floating, but the capital they represent, i.e., the construction of the railway, is fixed. A mill-owner who would sink in buildings and machinery apart of his capital out of proportion with the part reserved for the payment of wages and the purchase of raw material, would very soon find his mill stopped. The same holds good with a nation. Almost every commercial crisis in modern times has been connected with a derangement in the due proportion between floating and fixed capital. (MECW, XV, 20-1, emphasis added.) The short-run profit-making promotional dynamics of financial accumulation can overwhelm real accumulation such that the alloca tion of productive capital between its fixed and circulating compo nents is hopelessly distorted. The "Mobilier," instead of "mobilizing credit," sunk "floating capital" — liquid capital, in speculative bursts of real fixed investment for productive capital, but without regard to the general capacity for society to absorb the new boom in plant (i.e., without regard to the limits of the market) and without regard to the availability of working capital needed to run the new enterprises. Moreover, the international operations of the Crédit Mobilier extended this "immobilization" of capital to the whole of Europe. In this world capital truly inverts itself. Claims to capital, i.e., financial assets whose price is determined by the expectations of prospective future yields, are claims only to alienable property — which wage labor is not. Because waged labor is not collateralize able, the real substance of the creation of future value — labor — does not enter into the trade in claims to the future revenues generated by it. This leads to the curious phenomenon that while lenders will advance enormous sums of money for projected fixed capital constructions, they are less willing to advance money to foot the wage bill necessary to operate such enterprises — the view being that at least in the event of failure, recompense can be had from liquidating the physical plant, whereas no such claims can be made against labor. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 515 Work by economic historians has demonstrated Marx correc regarding the impact of the Crédit Mobiiieron French accumulat Born (1983, 77) writes: "The Crédit Mobiliers most glaring weakn lay in its extraordinary immobilization of capital." Bertrand G (1973, 293) reconstructs the Crédit Mobilier 's 1862 balance sheet onl to find an uncharacteristically high proportion of its assets imm lized in long-term industrial paper. Harvey (2013) documents h the Pereires' credit matrices promoted massive construction in ments, underwriting the "Haussmannization of Paris." He notes the resultant "overproduction" of high-value housing construct proved difficult to liquidate, immobilizing capital, leading to th bank's decline.15 One final consequence of this immobilization of capital and the consequent drying up of working capital addressed by Marx was the decapitalization of agriculture. Marx argued: Agriculture, never highly developed in France, has positively retro graded. . . . On the one hand we see taxes constantly increasing; on the other, decreasing labor... laborers being drafted ... by the railway and other public works — with the progressive withdrawal of capital from agricultural to speculative pursuits. (MECW, XV, 133-4.) III. THE FICTITIOUS NATURE OF STATE DEBT AND LENDER OF LAST RESORT Marx's third contribution on the subject of financial intermedia concerns the policy for a "lender of last resort" to restore confiden in the midst of a liquidity crisis. He questions whether further sions of fictitious capital — through conversions of private fina obligations into obligations of the state — can offer any hope resolution. In the case of France: When that crash comes, after an immensity of French interests have been involved, the Government of Bonaparte will seem justified in interfering with the Crédit Mobilier.... Louis Bonaparte, the imperial Socialist, will try to seize upon French industry by converting the debentures of the Crédit Mobilier into 15 Sraffa also addressed the matter of the "immobilization" of capital in his study of the 1920s bank crisis in Italy (Sraffa, 1922, 194). This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 516 SCIENCE SOCIETY State obligations. Will he prove to be more solvent than the Créd That is the question. (MECW, XV, 24.) Marx argued that financial panic prompts the mas holders to attempt the impossible — to cash in their pap tatives of value for direct command over real values. The ve structure of the private issuers, however, renders satisfa total demand impossible. The appeal is to state debt. It is the state can make good on the claims of security-holders b its powers to annex the nation's tax revenues. Again the question reemerges of whether money in su cial scheme continues to be advanced as capital, or, merel as revenue. To the degree the resolution of the private finan is achieved by making good on private debt through an i debt backed by taxes, all that is accomplished is a social losses; this affords no productive contribution to capit tion, save for the indirect effects of containing the scope o losses associated with stemming the run. On the occasion of the 1857 failure of the Guaranteed Discount Association, a large Hamburg bill-broker, Marx wrote: The guaranty of the Discount Association itself was found to need another guaranty in its turn, and the advances of the state, limited in their amount as well as the description of commodities to which they applied, became ... rela tively useless, at the same ratio that prices were going down. To uphold prices, and thus ward off the active cause of the distress, the state must pay the prices ruling before the outbreak of the commercial panic, and realize the value of bills of exchange which had ceased to represent anything but foreign failures. In other words, the fortune of the whole community, which the government represents, ought to make good for the losses of private capitalists. This sort of communism, where the mutuality is all on one side, seems rather attractive to the European capitalists. (MECW, XV, 405, emphasis added.)16 Marx argued that in the financial world characterized by a pyra miding of fictitious values, there always appears to be a need for a guarantor of some sort. The introduction of state debt resolves the uncertainty 16 Here Marx articulates the role of the state in "privatizing the gains and socializing the losses" from speculative financial behavior in the private sector. This theme was popularized byjoseph Stiglitz during the U. S. Occupy Wall Street protests in 2011. View his remarks on YouTube video, 12:39 (begin @ 3:00) posted by Noel Hefele, October 2, 2011, https://www.youtube .com/watch?v=2TF8L2DWhpw&feature=youtube This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 517 of the extant illiquidity of the present by substituting for it the uncertaint the future. While there is a significant degree of certainty regardin the state's capacity to exact reimbursement for today's borrowing ou of future taxation, it is significantly less certain that tomorrow's ta revenues will be exacted out of newly produced additions to capi as opposed to a decapitalization of existing capital, resulting fro the failure to impose surplus labor in the interim. In this man state debt provides a short-term solution for financial crises brou on by the breakdown in confidence in a world over-accumulated financial claims, but does so only by displacing the potential rupt in accumulation into the future on a larger scale. At best, in a cr the state's guarantee can make individual creditors whole, but on as a result of distributing the burden of losses over the entire societ Marx is quick to point out that the state is not aloof from the cl struggle in its attempts to assert itself as a "lender of last resort." In examination of the 1856 crisis he noted that war between the spe tors and industry had "increased suffering and discontent among workmen — especially at Lyons and in the south of France . .. [t degree . .. only to be compared with that which attended the crisis o 1847." Working-class discontent brewed against a financial backd in which speculation had rendered Crédit Mobilier issues so volati to be considered dangerous: The embarrassed companies harass the Government for leave to raise money by new emissions of shares and bonds. The Government, comprehend that this would simply amount to giving leave to further depreciation of t old securities in the market, attended by increased disturbance at the Bour dares not yield. On the other hand, the money must be found; the suspensi of the works would not only be bankruptcy but revolution. (MECW, XV, 13 Thus, the state's "lender of last resort" capabilities are by no me unambiguous. Aside from the traditional "moral hazard" proble there is the problem that intervention on the part of the state to res one institution may trigger a run across many sectors — where losse accrue as a result of the vulnerability of the existing stock of paper capital losses. At the same time, there exist definite social pressures associat with the fragility of the balance of class forces which impose constra at both ends of the policy spectrum: On the one hand, there are soci This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 518 SCIENCE & SOCIETY limits to the state's power to actively intervene to bail out fict capitals due to working-class refusal to accept the loss in purch power associated with either the new taxes or the inflation nece to finance the bailout. There is, in addition, the potential hazar generalizing the panic by calling attention to it with state interven On the other hand, there are social limits to the state's ability n bail out (in an effort to discipline economic units prone to m hazard) due to working-class refusal to accept the loss of inco associated with the attendant rise in unemployment that accomp failing enterprises. It is important to note that for Marx the future uncertainty a ciated with the substitution of state debt for bad debt, during cris is not a question of the degree of commodity-backing of statepaper currency, as suggested by proponents of the Currency Sc Rather, it is tied to the uncertainty of capital's command over fut labor. One hundred percent commodity-money will not prevent cr and the devaluation of financial claims. The presence of mone intrinsic value will not resolve the dilemma of a credit mechanism built on the promulgation of paper representatives of values issued in anticipation of their real labor counterparts in production: In Hamburg ... there is no money but silver. There exists no paper circula tion at all.. .. still the panic not only rages there most severely, but since the appearance of general commercial crisis — Hamburg has been their favorite arena. (MECW, XV, 406.) This has contemporary relevance, to wit, the "gold bugs" and the modern clamor to establish a 100% reserves gold standard to restore stability in money and financial markets.17 Dowd (1991) demonstrated that a directly convertible gold standard is predisposed to spasmodic liquidity crises, since the market for specie can only clear by forcing up interest rates. For Marx, simply "rushing to gold" does not guarantee the preservation of value. What is central is money's command over labor and its product. The demand for money is contingent on the guarantee that holding it will not result in the loss of command over future labor relative to present labor. The fact that money of intrinsic value possesses value itself as a produced commodity does not explain 17 See the incessant calls for a return to the Gold Standard by the CATO Institute. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 519 its command over labor. The question becomes: What determines th particular instrument that serves as the generally accepted means exchange and will it continue to function as means of exchange aft the crisis? The fact that the state determines the particular commo ties to serve as the generally accepted means of exchange is mor important than the fact that the money instrument is a commodi of intrinsic value. IV. THE CRÉDIT MOBILIER AND THE RESTRUCTURING OF CAPITALIST PROPERTY The fourth theme is the role of the Crédit Mobilier in restructuring "socializing" capitalist property. Through its patronization of lim liability joint-stock companies, the Crédit Mobilier played an impor role in leveraging operations to facilitate the progressive annihilati of small individual private capitals which ultimately led to an imme centralization of capital. Proprietors became speculators, losers bankrupt, capital was centralized, and a few industrial magn emerged to oversee a vast accumulation of capital — command its total amount, yet only responsible to their relatively diminis share in it. Marx, not unlike Veblen later, argued that recklessness the management of the national capital increased with this separati of ownership from control (see Veblen, 1904). The role of the credit mechanism in the concentration and cen tralization of capital is developed in great detail in Volumes I and III of Capital. What is unique about Marx's early discussion in the Tribune articles, however, is, first, his rejection of the notion that competi tive or laissez-faire banking has a basis for existence, and second, his insistence that the inevitable concentration of capital fueled by the credit mechanism leads to a corresponding concentration of labor.18 Marx maintained that laissez-faire banking is merely a pretext for the concentration of capital and is itself a contradictory and ephemeral state of financial organization. He examined the chronic battles for financial liberalization waged by the Pereire brothers, who sought to carve out a competitive place for investment banking in the French financial landscape dominated by Rothschild's haute banque. 18 Stephen Hymer (1960) similarly argued that the organizational development of capital and labor are organically linked. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 520 SCIENCE & SOCIETY Yet, behind the call for financial deregulation, Marx noted tha Pereire's true aim was to annex other people's money so as to age the Crédit Mobiliers operations and realize the St. Simonist of commanding all of French banking. For Marx, monopoly i highest stage of competition in banking. Second, on the labor front, Marx argued that the Crédit Mo was spawning a modern form of Fourier's Industrial Feudalism The application of joint-stock companies to industry marks a new ep the economical life of modern nations.... By this contrivance, propri have been converted into shareholders, i.e., speculators. The concent of capital has been accelerated.... A sort of industrial kings have been ated ... being responsible only to the amount of their shares.... Beneat oligarchic Board of Directors is placed a bureaucratic body of the pr managers .. . and beneath them ... an enormous and daily-swelling m of mere wage laborers ... who ... become more dangerous in direct to the decreasing number of [capital's] representatives. (MECW, XV Marx was quick to point out that relations between capital and in conjunction with the heightened climate of speculation aggra tensions in the class struggle. V. THE POLITICAL ROLE OF THE CRÉDIT MOBILIER "IMPERIAL SOCIALISM" AND NAPOLEON'S BID TO BUY TIME IN THE FRENCH CLASS STRUGGLE The final theme in Marx's analysis is that financial institutions s a political role in accumulation and act chiefly in the interests o capitalist class. He examines the role of the Crédit Mobilier as a "fin cial arm" for Napoleon's consolidation of power. Napoleon need financial institution that would make him independent of Roths and the haute banque, who supported the House of Orleans and uncooperative when Napoleon was elected president of the seco French republic. Marx argued that Napoleon was forced to appear simultaneously as the robber and the patriarchal benefactor classes. He could not give to the one class without taking from the other, he could not satisfy his own wants and those of his followers without rob both ... to steal France in order to buy France — that was the great problem man had to solve ... [by] the one great resource that had carried him This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION the most difficult economical situations — CREDIT. (MECW, XV, 14-15, emphasis added.) Napoleon found it necessary to "buy time" to consolidate his rule. He required an independent arm of credit that would be "state serving" to counteract the strangulation of credit imposed by the disapproving haute banque. State credit offered the short-run illu sion of dissolving the class relation. Marx argued that it was for this reason Napoleon appealed to the St. Simonist banking tradition in France which "deluded itself with the dream that all the antagonism of classes must disappear before the creation of universal wealth by some new fangled scheme of public credit." It is in this context that Isaac and Emile Péreire appear as the financiers, if not the founders, of "Bonapartist Socialism." Napoleon looked with favor on the Crédit Mobilier and sought to gain control of French industry with its Lilliputian capital outlay. Marx characterized the project as "Imperial Socialism": The Crédit Mobilier proposes to favor... the "public works" — which means, to make industry and public works in general dependent on the favor of the Crédit Mobilier, and therefore on the individual favor of Bonaparte.... What does the Crédit Mobilier propose? To substitute for all these different stocks issued by different joint-stock companies, one common stock issued by the Crédit MobilieriXseM. But how can it effect this? Buying up all the bonds, shares, debentures, etc. — in one word, all the paper of a concern — is buying up the concern itself. Hence the Crédit Mobilier avows the intention of making itself the proprietor, and Napoleon the Little the supreme director, of the whole varied industry of France. This is what we call Imperial Socialism. (MECW, XV, 11.) In contradistinction to "revolutionary socialism" — the direct expro priation of capitalist property by the working class — Marx used the term "Imperial Socialism" for the gradual destruction of private prop erty through its incorporation into the hands of an alienated state — i.e., a socialization of capital without elimination of the class relation. Lastly, Marx noted that with all forms of credit, loans eventually "come due." He observed that the greatest despair among the bour geoisie in 1857 was the sense that the victory over the 1848 revolution — a victory that was genuinely purchased on credit — was about to collapse as the real terms of the loan, measured in terms of the class This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 521 522 SCIENCE äf SOCIETY relation, came "due." The borrowed time purchased to displace t contradictions of the class struggle of 1848 to the future was now up Settlement day, brought on by the agitation of the working class would provoke a massive devaluation of the fictitious values that provided a temporary buffer of prosperity between the classes: The anxiety of the upper classes in Europe is as intense as their disapp ment. . . . With a view to save their property they did everything in th power to put down the Revolution.... They are now discovering that th were themselves the instruments of a revolution in property greater than contemplated by the revolutionists of 1848. A general bankruptcy is staring them in the face, which they know to be coincidental with the settlem day of the great pawning shop in Paris.... They know that every marke over-imported; that every fraction of the proprietary classes .. . has b drawn into the vortex of the speculative mania; that no European coun has escaped it; and that the demands of Governments on their tax-pay people have been stretched to the last point.... a social revolution broug about by no underground plots of the secret societies among the work classes, but by the public contrivances of the Crédit Mobiliers of the ru classes. (MECW, XV, 114.) While credit may provide temporary relief from the barriers to a mulation posed by working-class power, credit can never overcom the barrier of the class relation itself. Capital's victory over the Revo tions of 1848, through the utilization of credit, proved to be its chie vulnerability one decade later. Further Research on Financial Intermediation and Crisis in Modern Context The five propositions gleaned from Marx's analysis of the French Crédit Mobilier should provide insight on how to think about banking and finance in the larger context of contemporary accumulation. We have examined Marx's work on the financial form and content of accu mulation, enumerating the specific role of financial intermediaries in the production of volatility and crisis in 19th-century France. The lessons of the Crédit Mobilier, properly interpreted in modern times, must also be grounded in the larger analytical context of Capital and the Grundrisse. Finance at all points must be reconciled with capital's capacity to discipline labor and harvest surplus value at a future date. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 523 The uncertainty of "money as capital" is the uncertainty of the c struggle itself. This methodological premise separates Marx from post-Keynesians, both in terms of understanding the forces pro ing speculative debt-deflation crises and the spectrum of reme proposed as cures. Each of the five propositions suggests a framework for "siftin financial events in modern context. Contemporary lessons eme from a reexamination of the systemic misallocation of financial capi that produced the 2008 housing bubble and the corresponding growt of fictitious capital in derivatives markets that circulated the crisis g ally. Debt-deflation proceeded without salvation in the imposition surplus labor. Capital was "immobilized," applied out of proportio the housing sector, in the name of "mobilizing" it through the issue mortgage-backed securities. Prospects for the realization of advan as "capital" proved unlikely, working from a foundation of securitiz revenue streams, notwithstanding efforts to insure returns with the tiary securitization of collateralized debt obligations (CDOs). Bailo in the form of Central Bank credits and augmenting state debt prevent a more profound collapse. The resulting 2010 sovereign d crisis, however, raised the stakes for severe redisciplining of labor i weak states while postponing the day of reckoning of finance "as cap tal" to a future date. Substantive restructuring of capitalist prop ensued via a global redistribution across failed financial institutio "accumulation through dispossession" proceeded apace across cla lines as homeowners and debtors generally surrendered propert through mass foreclosures. Debtor resistance, Occupy Wall Stre and a sustained global spectrum of mobilizations against austeri fueled political tension, deepening the crisis. Continued applica of monetary emission and fiscal stimulus via state debt served to "bu time," in attempts to consolidate social control. A more thorough "sifting" of contemporary financial cri through the filter of Marx's propositions on financial interme tion is a project for future research. Lessons from the Crédit Mobili do, however, suggest that reform palliatives afford no cure. Tweakin information access and regulation on trades will not erase the st tural predisposition to speculative excess. Crisis resolution with active resistance will only provision the socialization of losses to pay the cleanup of devalued assets liquidated to realize privatized ga Finally, well-intentioned calls for policies of "bank nationalizat This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 524 SCIENCE & SOCIETY that fail to envision the elimination of the class relation, are see only produce a depraved socialization of capital and the inevitab reemergence of crises at the level of the state. Department of Economics Babson College Wellesley, MA 02157 ricciardi@babson. edu REFERENCES Bologna, Sergio. 1974. "Moneta e Crisi: Marx Corrispondente della 'New York Da Tribune,' 1856-57." Primo Maggio, 1. Born, Karl Erich. 1983. International Banking in the 19th and 20th Centuries. Londo New York: Berg/St. Martin's. Brunnermeier, Markus, and Martin Oehmke. 2012. "Bubbles, Financial Crises, an Systemic Risk." NBER Working Papers, Working Paper 18398. Cameron, Rondo, E. 1961. France and the Economic Development of Europe. Princeto New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Caffentzis, George. 2013. In Letters of Blood and Fire: Work, Machines, and the Crisis o Capitalism. Oakland, California: PM Press. Darityjr., William, and Bobbie Horn. 1985. "Rudolf Hilferding: The Dominion of C italism and the Domination of Gold." American Economic Review (May), 363-369 Davidson, Paul. 1978. Money in the Real World. 2nd Edition. London: Macmillan. Dowd, Kevin. 1991. "Financial Instability in a 'Direcdy Convertible' Gold Standard Southern Economic Journal, 57:94 (January). Fisher, Irving. 1933. "Debt-Deflation." Economica, 1:4 (October), 337-357. Fohlen, Claude. 1973. "France 1700-1914." In Carlo M. Cipolla, ed., The Fontana Economic History of Europe. Vol. 4: The Emergence of Industrial Societies. Londo Collins/Fontana. Fortune, Peter. 1991. "Stock Market Efficiency: An Autopsy?" Pp. 17-40 in New Engla Economic Review (March-April). Gershenkron, Alexander. 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Ca bridge, Massachusetts: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Gille, Bertrand. 1973. "Banking and Industrialization in Europe, 1730-1914." In Ca Cipolla, ed., Fontana Economic History of Europe, Vol. 3. London: Collins-Fontana Graeber, David. 2011. Debt: The First 5,000 Years. New York: Melville House. Gurley, J. G., and E. S. Shaw. 1955. "Financial Aspects of Economic Developmen American Economic Review, 45:4 (September), 515-538. Hahn, Frank H. 1965. "On Some Problems of Proving the Existence of an Equilibriu in a Monetary Economy." In F. H. Hahn and F. P. R. Brechling, eds., The Theory of Interest Rates. London: Macmillan. Harris, Laurence. 1985. "Marx's Theory of Finance and a Critique of 'Finan Capital.'" Paper delivered at the New York ASSA Conference, December 28. This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms MARX ON FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 525 Harvey, David. 1982. The Limits to Capital. Oxford, England: Basil B . 2011. The Enigma of Capital and the Crises of Capitalism. London . 2013. Paris, Capital of Modernity. New York: Routledge. Hicks, John R. 1967. Critical Essays in Monetary Theory. Oxford, E Hoover, Kevin D. 1990 (1988). The New Classical Macroeconomics: A Oxford, England: Basil Blackwell. Hymer, Stephen. 1976 (1960). The International Operations ofNational F Massachusetts: MIT Press. Kareken, John H., and Neil Wallace, eds. 1980. Models of Monetary Economics. Min neapolis, Minnesota: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Keeton, William. 1984. "Deposit Insurance and the Deregulation of Deposit Rates." Economic Review, Federal Reserve Kansas City (April), 28-46. Kindleberger, Charles P. 1978. Manias, Panics, and Crashes. New York: Basic Books. . 1983. "Financial Institutions and Economic Development: A Comparison of Great Britain and France in the 18th and 19th Centuries." Seminar Paper No. 234, Institute for International Economic Studies, University of Stockholm. . 1986 (1982). "Collective Memory vs. Rational Expectations: Some Historical Puzzles in Macro-Economic Behavior." In Charles P. Kindleberger, Keynesianism vs. Monetarism and Other Essays in Financial History. London: Allen & Unwin. Marx, Karl, and Frederick Engels. 2004. Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Collected Works (MECW). Volumes 1-50. New York: International Publishers. McKinnon, Ronald. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution. Minksy, Hyman. 1982. "The Financial Instability Hypothesis: A Restatement" In Can "It" Happen Again1? Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe. Morais, Herbert M. 1948. "Marx and Engels on America." Science à? Society, XII:1 Winter), 3-21. O'Brien, D. P., and C. Keyder. 1978. Economic Growth in Britain and France, 1780-1914: Two Paths to the 20th Century. London: Allen & Unwin. Parsons, John E. 1988. "Bubble, Bubble, How Much Trouble? Financial Markets, Capi talist Development, and Capitalist Crises." Science & Society, 52:3 (Fall), 260-289. Perelman, Michael. 1987. "Political Economy and the Press: Karl Marx and Henry Carey at the New York Tribune." Chapter 1 of Marx's Crisis Theory. Totowa, New Jersey: Greenwood Press. Ricciardi, Joseph. 1985. Essays on the Role of Money and Finance in Economic Development. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Texas. Shleifer, Andrei, and Lawrence Summers. 1990. "The Noise Trader Approach to Finance." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4:2 (Spring), 19-34. Shaw, Edward. 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development. London/Toronto, Canada: Oxford University Press. Sraffa, Piero. 1922. "The Bank Crisis in Italy." Economic journal, 32:126 (June), 178-197. Stiglitz, Joseph E., ed. 1990. "Symposium on Bubbles." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4:2 (Spring), 13-18. Taylor, Lance. 1983. Structuralist Macroeconomics. New York: Basic Books. Tirole,Jean. 1989. "Theories of Speculation." Pp. 351-61 in Sudipto Bhattacharya and George Constantinides, eds., Financial Markets and Incomplete Information: This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 526 SCIENCE 6s SOCIETY Frontiers of Modem Financial Theory. Toto Tobin, James. 1968. "Notes on Optimal Monetar 76 (July-August), 843-46. . 1980. "Discussion ofWallace's Overlapping In John Kareken and Neil Wallace, eds., Mod Minnesota: Federal Reserve Bank of Min Vehlen, Thorstein. 1904. Theory of Business E Wood, John. 1981. "Financial Intermediari Journal of Monetary Economics, 8:2, 145-163 This content downloaded from 142.150.190.39 on Mon, 02 Aug 2021 02:30:26 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms